Improving Health Care for Canadians
William McArthur, Cynthia Ramsay, and Michael
Walker
SECTION I
From 1867 to 1984-a brief historical perspective
The BNA Act of 1867 (and the Constitution Act of 1982) gave the federal government
responsibility for national health concerns such as quarantine, marine hospitals, and
health services for aboriginals and the armed forces. [This section draws on numerous documents. Important among these are: The
Royal Commission on Health Services, vols 1 and 2, Ottawa: Queens Printer, 1964 and 1965;
A. Crichton, D. Hsu, and S. Tsang, Canada's Health Care System, Ottawa: CHA Press, 1994;
Michael Walker, "Anatomy of a Conundrum: Canadian Health Care in the 1980s," in
Policies and Prescriptions, Australia: The Centre for Independent Studies, 1986, pp.
23-43.] The provinces were
given control over local health matters such as hospitals, asylums, and charities in and
for the province. Since health care was identified with hospitals, it was considered to be
a provincial responsibility.
In the 19th and early 20th centuries, Canadians paid doctors, hospitals, pharmacists, and
other health care providers out of pocket when they received a treatment or service; user
fees were the method of payment. The government funded public health services only. For
those people who could not afford to pay for their care, there were three types of social
safety net: philanthropy, social assistance, and mutual aid. In larger cities, voluntary
organizations proliferated, giving aid to specific groups of low-income people.
Despite the availability of alternative forms of aid, municipalities assumed most of the
responsibility for looking after the poor. By 1914, they also monitored infection control,
set up sanitary services, and provided some public nursing. Many offered part-time public
health work to doctors. Because of the benevolent nature of their work, many people
thought that these doctors should be guaranteed work as personal practitioners for the
rest of their time, and, in 1916, the Municipal Doctors' Scheme was introduced in Sarnia,
Saskatchewan; doctors were paid from taxes to provide clinical services to residents. The
scheme was soon introduced in other provinces as well: in rural areas, mining towns, and
heavily industrialized towns. About the same time, municipalities began seeking to join
together to become hospital funding authorities so that they could set up hospitals to
attract doctors (whose incomes would be guaranteed by the Municipal Doctors' Scheme).
During the Depression in the 1930s, there was general financial hardship, and the medical
profession was not exempt. Organized medicine responded to the situation by pressuring
both the federal and provincial levels of government to provide some type of first-dollar
health insurance for low income persons and the unemployed. The Depression prompted the
growth of medically sponsored prepayment plans and non-profit hospital insurance sponsored
by provincial hospital associations.
Universal health insurance was first proposed in 1919 by Mackenzie King as part of the
Liberal party campaign platform. It was recommended by organized labour on a regular basis
thereafter. The government of British Columbia actually passed an Act to Provide for a
Provincial System of Health Insurance in 1936 but it was rejected by the medical
profession and, in the end, it was never implemented. In Ontario, the entrepreneurial
spirit was stronger than the spirit for government intervention. Doctors in Ontario were
forming prepayment schemes, customarily offering first-dollar coverage and providing
direct payment from the plan to the practitioner. In Windsor, doctors formed the Essex
County Medical Society and began a non-profit medical services prepayment program for
hospital care that was adopted by Toronto doctors (the Blue Cross). During the 1940s, as
economic growth in Canada continued, more people contributed to these types of plans for
both hospital insurance and medical care. In 1943, privately operated hospital insurance
began in B.C., and by the early 1950s most Canadians had some form of hospital insurance,
whether publicly provided, non-profit or commercial.
In 1945, there was a federal-provincial conference (the Dominion Provincial Conference on
Reconstruction) to consider programs of social reform. The conference produced a draft
health care bill for the provinces, modelled partly on the U.K. National Health System
which was influenced by Britain's main reformer of the time, Lord Beveridge, who advocated
that the state provide social security programs for its citizens from cradle to grave.
Patients were to register with family physicians in health regions. These family
physicians would be responsible for their patient "lists" and would be paid on a
capitation basis administered under the direction of a commission representing both
consumers and the professions.
The plan was not enacted because it was seen by the governments of Ontario and Quebec as a
federal encroachment on the provincial authority granted them in the BNA Act, and many
provinces favoured free market insurance. Instead of a full health insurance plan, the
federal government made grants available to the provinces for planning and hospital
construction through the Hospital Construction Grants Program (HCGP) of 1948. Under this
legislation, the federal government completely funded the building of hospitals virtually
anywhere in Canada. It is not surprising that over the next 12 years the number of
hospital beds in Canada increased at double the rate of the expansion in population, and
thereby created a bed surplus, the need for which had not been established.
By 1950, Saskatchewan (1947), British Columbia (1948), and Alberta (1950), had enacted
universal hospital insurance plans. Other provinces followed suit. As a result of the
HCGP, the number of hospital beds in Canada increased, costs increased, and the provinces
soon asked the federal government to legislate the nation-wide universal hospital
insurance it had offered them back in 1945. Instead, in 1957, the Hospital Insurance and
Diagnostic Services Act (HIDS) was passed. Prior to 1957, Canada's health prepayment
system was a composite of public and private plans: provincial medical and hospital
coverage for low income individuals, universal hospital insurance provided by a number of
provinces, private medical and hospital insurance on a non-profit basis sponsored by
provider associations, and a limited amount by for-profit private insurers. By 1961,
however, all of the provinces had adopted universal hospital insurance because the federal
government was paying 50 percent of the average provincial costs.
The main problem with HIDS was that services were insured and eligible for cost-sharing
only if they were provided in hospitals; there were no incentives to use less expensive
sites (i.e., home care). Also, there were no organizational framework impositions on
hospitals-there was no accountability for the funds required. If a hospital did not spend
its entire allotted annual budget, the province would reclaim the unspent funds. However,
if a hospital needed additional funding, the province would provide it. This created
disincentives to run a hospital efficiently. The number of in-patient beds increased by a
further 34 percent from 1960 to 1970, while the Canadian population increased by only 19
percent.
In 1964, the Hall Commission made its report, recommending that the federal government
cost-share a universal medical insurance model and that medical services delivery should
be reorganized. The Medical Care Act of 1966 (implemented in 1968) did not incorporate the
reorganization recommendation. However, it did provide federal-provincial cost-sharing for
services provided by physicians (only). To qualify for funding, a province's program had
to be:
universal-it had to cover all residents of a province,
portable-it had to cover residents of one province requiring medical services in another province,
comprehensive-it had to cover all medically necessary services, and
publicly administered-a non-profit program.
Saskatchewan and British Columbia qualified
for funding immediately. B.C. had initiated the B.C. Medical Plan in 1965. Alberta and
Ontario were slow to join because there was strong lobbying by private insurance
interests, and Quebec endured a specialists' strike. By 1971 though, all provinces and
territories had joined the plan.
Hospital costs continued to grow, in part because the federal government had no control
over total provincial expenditures, and in part because the provinces had little incentive
to contain costs. As a result, the cost-sharing agreement was replaced in 1977 by Bill
C-37, the Federal-Provincial Fiscal Arrangements and Established Programs Financing Act
(EPF). The EPF reduced the direct federal contribution to health care and tied any
increases in federal payments to GNP growth. To compensate, federal income and corporate
taxes were decreased to create "tax room" for the provinces. The conversion from
a federal-provincial cost-sharing agreement to one based on block funding had little if
anything to do with any desire by either level of government to improve medical or
hospital care delivery. The EPF allowed the federal government to limit its health care
expenditures and it gave the provinces greater control over how the money for education
and health was to be spent.
The Canada Health Act
In 1984, in spite of much opposition from both organized medicine and from provincial
governments, the federal government passed the Canada Health Act (CHA) which reiterated
the requirements of the 1966 Medical Care Act and added another: accessibility. Federal
payments to the provinces would be reduced, on a dollar-for-dollar basis, by the amount of
user charges by hospitals and extra billing by physicians. Direct federal prohibition of
these fees was impossible because, constitutionally, health care is a provincial
responsibility.
As table 1 indicates, there has been a steady decline of federal financial support for
health care since the late 1970s. In 1995, the federal government announced that it would
cut federal transfers to the provinces further. As federal funding decreases, these
funding arrangements will become less and less binding, and provinces will find themselves
with more freedom to reform their health care systems.
Click here to view Table 1: Provincial Funding as a
Percentage of Total Federal and Provincial Funding of Health Care
Much of the recent debate about health care has focused on the sanctity of the CHA and its
principles, rather than whether or not adherence to these principles actually creates a
healthy population or permits health care delivery systems to adapt. The federal
government and some provincial governments are defending the act as an essential pillar of
the future health care edifice. Others, including Premier Klein of Alberta, have expressed
concern that the CHA is now an impediment to the kinds of changes that the provinces must
make to respond to both the fiscal and the health needs of their citizens.
The ideological divide, of course, is the Alberta premier's idea that there may be an
increased role for private clinics and other private health providers in the health care
system of the future. Echoing the long-expressed opinion of The Fraser Institute, critics
of the CHA note that the act is a kind of Great Canadian Myth honoured largely in the
breach. Here we explore the sense in which such an assessment might be accurate, and why
the Canada Health Act ought to be abandoned in favour of a modern, relevant alternative.
Universality
The principle of universality "requires" that 100 percent of the residents of a
province be entitled to insured services. In spite of the fact that low income residents
are exempted from the modest premium which must be paid in B.C., it is estimated by the
B.C. Ministry of Health that only 97 percent of the residents of the province are actually
covered by the Medical Services Plan, the provincial insurer. Therefore, contrary to the
"requirement" that every British Columbian be insured, over 100,000 people are
not publicly insured in B.C. A testimony to this situation can be found in the emergency
departments of some downtown Vancouver hospitals, where about 10 percent of the British
Columbians coming in for emergency care have no medical coverage. [W. McArthur, Personal communication with Dr. J.M.
Etherington, Head, Emergency Department, St. Paul's Hospital, Vancouver, B.C.] In provinces that charge insurance premiums, the poor, the mentally
challenged, and a significant number of healthy young adults who reject the thought of
illness or accident have no coverage. Universal medical insurance is not a reality in
Canada.
However, this does not mean that people are denied care. An uninsured person arriving at a
hospital or in a doctor's waiting room with an urgent condition is treated. The
universality provisions of the act are unimportant in that they are not being met, and
there are few individual consequences as a result.
Accessibility
The existence of premiums neither hinders nor guarantees a person's access to medical
care. There are data showing that access to service in Canada is not equal. For example,
much of the queue jumping in British Columbia is for non-medical reasons. Politicians,
health professionals, and the influential often obtain care more rapidly than most other
citizens. [D.H.A. Amoko, R.E. Modrow,
and J.K.H. Tan, "Surgical Waiting Lists II: Current Practices and Future Directions
Using the Province of British Columbia as a Test Study," Healthcare Management FORUM,
vol 5, no. 4, 1992.] As well, any wealthy Canadian has
the option of receiving more expedient treatment in the U.S. or in another province with
shorter hospital waiting times. Contrary to the belief that within Canada there is equal
access to health care services, a Fraser Institute study has shown that waiting times for
surgical procedures vary greatly across the country, with wealthier provinces tending to
have shorter hospital waiting lists. ["Waiting
Your Turn: Hospital Waiting Lists in Canada," Fraser Forum Critical Issues Bulletin,
various editions.]
An Ontario cancer treatment study has shown that waiting times for cancer treatment in
Canada are substantially longer than in the U.S. and longer than the time radiation
oncologists consider to be the medically acceptable maximum. [W.J. Mackillop, "Waiting for Radiotherapy in Canada and the
U.S.," presented at the 36th Annual American Society for Therapeutic Radiology in San
Francisco, October 3, 1994.]
While unequal access is a fact of the Canadian health care system, controlling costs
through the use of waiting lists, i.e., through rationing, is not accepted by the public
as a satisfactory cost containment measure. This was revealed in British Columbia when the
government, in response to pressure from vociferous patients waiting for treatment,
allocated more than $25 million towards cutting waiting lists for surgery and to reduce
waits for publicly funded magnetic resonance imaging (MRI) machines. [Office of the Premier of British Columbia,
"$25 Million to Reduce Cancer Treatment and Surgery Waitlists," News Release,
April 4, 1996.]
The latter development reflected the fact that there are two private MRI clinics in
Vancouver charging $595 to $750 a test. They are open 6 days a week and guarantee test
results within 48 hours. They are evidently fulfilling demand for diagnostic testing which
is not being met by the public system.
Portability
The Canadian who gets sick in Florida or California rapidly discovers that effective
portability ceases at the Canadian border. Quebecers who find themselves requiring medical
services in another Canadian province must pay out of pocket for those services. Upon
returning home, they will be reimbursed only for the amount these services would have cost
if performed in Quebec. This occurs because there is no reciprocal billing agreement
between Quebec and the other nine provinces.
Comprehensive
The list of services covered by the CHA is not comprehensive by any means. Hospital
insurance only covers services performed in a hospital, and medical care insurance covers
services performed by a restricted set of primary providers; they both only cover services
designated as medically necessary and there is no consensus on what constitutes medically
necessary services. Since health is a provincial responsibility, different provincial
insurers cover different procedures.
Although B.C. ostensibly would like to "preserve Medicare," earlier this year it
was considering de-insuring non-essential services. For example, the removal of warts may
no longer be covered by the Medical Services Plan. This procedure is no longer covered in
Alberta, Saskatchewan, Manitoba, or New Brunswick. Across the nation, coverage varies
widely in the areas of cosmetic surgery, reproductive services, and general health
maintenance. For example, reversals of tubal ligations and vasectomies are always covered
in Ontario, Quebec, New Brunswick, and the Yukon; they are sometimes covered in Nova
Scotia, Newfoundland, and the Northwest Territories, while patients in B.C., Alberta,
Saskatchewan, Manitoba, and P.E.I. must pay for these procedures. Another example is
electrolysis, which is covered only in B.C. and in three other provinces or territories. [Vancouver Sun, March 23, 1995, pp. B1 and B12.]
Some people argue that de-insuring services would not save money, while others claim that
de-insuring would make it harder for the government to control the quality of services,
and thus leaving procedures to the private sector could cause the public sector more
expense in the end. Health economist Robert G. Evans from the University of British
Columbia gives the following example to support these claims. Even if in vitro
fertilization is not covered publicly, "a couple's sickly quadruplets will end up, at
public expense, in the hospital." [Ibid,
p. B12.] All of this will cost the public system more
money in the end, presumably.
Evans's comment betrays the implicit controversy about medical necessity that underlies
the debate about the boundaries of the public health care system. It also shows how
shallow are the arguments against private sector participation in the delivery of health
care services since there are all sorts of activities that might increase the number of
medically necessary procedures-from skiing accidents to excessive consumption of alcohol,
fats, and some vitamins. This does not mean that the public sector ought to be the
exclusive operator of ski hills, bars, restaurants, or health food stores!
The problem is that, as has recently been determined in Oregon, while it is possible to
rank medical interventions according to their efficacy and necessity, the ultimate
question of how far down the list the public sector will go is not a medical question but
a fiscal one. In the end, all questions about medical care are questions about economics.
It is the denial of this central fact which is the Achilles heel of the Canada Health Act
and the main reason it is proving to be an impediment to the smooth and effective
adaptation of the health care sector in Canada.
Publicly Administered
This provision of the CHA, reflecting the British Beveridge Report which inaugurated
socialized medicine in the U.K., is a purely ideological manifesto. There is nothing about
the principles of universality, accessibility, portability, and comprehensiveness that
require health care to be publicly administered. Indeed, it is increasingly believed by
some analysts that the publicly administered principle is incompatible with the others and
that it is the single biggest impediment to achieving them. Nevertheless, it is the
central belief of those who support the status quo.
The main argument in favour of government administration of the health care system is that
it will minimize the cost of administration which would otherwise be involved. A
multiplicity of insurers would entail duplication of billing and administrative functions,
as occurs in the United States. Indeed, studies have shown that great administrative
savings can be achieved if duplication is eliminated. What is not often appreciated is
that there are also costs involved when there is only one supplier-something which has
been recognized by economists and others with respect to the markets for all other goods
and services. In fact, in most democratic countries, regulatory agencies exist to prevent
monopolies from occurring. The reason monopoly is feared is the deterioration which
typically occurs in the markets it visits-including higher prices, lower quality of
service, lagged innovation, and loss of consumer satisfaction.
The same problems typify the markets for health care. For example, government is the
monopoly employer of health care personnel. When labour negotiations break down in a
monopoly system, there are no other sources of care available, and the patients pay the
consequences. Strikes, such as the 17-day B.C. nurses' strike in 1989, effectively shut
down most of a province's health care system. [Michael Walker, Wall Street Journal, October 18, 1991, p. A15.] As a result, treatments are delayed and patients suffer
unnecessarily. This type of cost is difficult if not impossible to measure and is never
reported by the proponents of monopoly health care.
Summary
The post-World War II history of health care in Canada is one characterized by a
constitutionally constrained federal government exercising its fiscal powers, with
taxpayers' money, to make itself a major player in the health care system. Initially,
federal funds were used to build hospitals, the need for which had not been proven.
Universal insurance for hospital care ensued-insurance for care which in many cases could
and should have been provided in less expensive and more effective environments than
hospitals. Having paid for the construction of the hospitals and for the care provided in
them, it remained only for the federal government to pay doctors to work there, and this
it accomplished with the Medical Care Act. The Canada Health Act merely reaffirmed the
leading role the federal government had cast for itself as the main provider and funder of
health care in Canada.
Canadian health care and the OECD
Canada is a member of both the Group of Seven (G7) and the Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD). It shares many commonalities with the other countries
in these groups. While there are many ways of examining and comparing the health of
similar populations, a few generally accepted measures help to place Canada within the
context of its OECD partners. [Much of
the information here is drawn from OECD data released in May 1995, which provide
statistics to the end of 1994. Comparative information is sometimes incomplete. Thus, it
is sometimes necessary to use data from different years. The most recent available data
have been used throughout.]
By placing Canada in an international context, one can see how myths have come to define
the Canadian "health care crisis." Working from these myths, the authors will
now show why recent attempts at health care reform in Canada may be misdirected.
Myth: Health Expenditures are Directly Related to Health Status
The Japanese have the longest life expectancy, at 82.2 years for females and 76.1 years
for males (see figure 1). These figures are much lower for Mexico, where the average life
expectancy of females is 74.4 years and for males is 68.4 years. In most OECD countries,
however, females can expect to live 79 to 81 years and males 72 to 75. Canada is no
exception: life expectancy for females is 81.2 years and for males 74.9 years. Perhaps
surprisingly, life expectancy is not directly related to amount of money spent on health
care. The percentage of gross domestic product (GDP) spent by OECD countries on health
care varies considerably (see table 2). [Figures
for total expenditure on health as a percentage of GDP are 1993 OECD data.] For example, Denmark spends 6.7 percent of its GDP on health care
while the U.S. spends 14.1 percent; yet life expectancy data are quite similar for both
countries. Japan, at 7.3 percent, has one of the lower expenditures on health as a
percentage of GDP but has notably longer life expectancies.
Click here to view Figure 1: OECD Life Expectancy at Birth
(1992)
Click here to view Table 2: Total and Public Expenditure on
Health Care Expressed as a Percentage of GDP (1993)
A more detailed examination of life expectancy information for Canada reveals some
interesting trends. Both males and females can expect to live, on average, about five
years longer than they did 20 years ago, but the progressive increase in life expectancy
observed over the last 50 years appears to have halted, and the OECD reports that the
number of years Canadians can expect to live in good health actually declined by 2.3 years
for females (see figure 2) and 0.4 years for males between 1978 and 1991. At least part of
this decline appears to be statistical artifact, since data collection criteria changed
between 1978 and 1986. However, the same standards applied in 1986 and 1991 and the data
show that overall life expectancy at birth for Canadians declined in that time. [Statistics Canada, Health Reports 1995, vol. 7, no.
1, p. 56. Preliminary reports indicate that this downward trend was not maintained in
1994. See Statistics Canada, The Daily, May 24, 1996.]
Click here to view Figure 2: Female Good Health Life
Expectancy From Reporting OECD Countries
The reason for this change is not obvious. However, there is a consistency between this
development and the recognition in recent surveys that there is an increasing amount of
rationing in the health care system. ["Waiting
Your Turn, Hospital Waiting Lists in Canada," Fraser Forum Critical Issues Bulletin,
various editions.] It has
long been known that when rationing emerges in a health care system, those most likely to
feel the impact are the elderly. [E.A.
Binney and C.L. Estes, "The Retreat of the State and Its Transfer of
Responsibility," International Journal of Health Sciences, vol. 18, 1988, pp. 83-96;
A.L. McKinnon, "`We've Got the Best Cared For Seniors in the Country': Impacts of
Health Care Cuts and Reforms on Older Albertans," Canadian Association on Gerontology
Meeting, Vancouver, B.C., Oct. 28, 1995; O. Agbayewa, "Suicides Among Elderly Linked
to Societal Factors," Medical Post, vol. 7, no. 26, Oct. 10, 1995.] The reason is that in a classic triage system, since those who are
older benefit less (i.e. for fewer years) than those who are younger, older patients tend
to be placed at the end of the queue.
Myth: A Publicly Funded and Controlled Health System is the Most Efficient and
Effective Way to Ensure Quality Health Care
In terms of total health purchasing, the U.S. and Canada both spend in excess of 10
percent of GDP (see table 2). Other countries with reputations for excellent care,
however-including Japan, New Zealand, and the U.K.-all spend less than 8 percent of their
GDP on health care. A review of public expenditures on health care reveals a slightly
different picture. Big spenders in this category include Canada, France, Belgium, and
Norway, for which more than 7.0 percent of GDP represents taxpayer financing of health
care. Canada's public expenditure on health care exceeds that of the U.K., Australia, and
New Zealand by 1.5 percent of GDP or more, and the U.S. by 1.2 percent of GDP. These four
countries, all with substantially different health care systems, provide a comparable
level of care to Canada, and spend a substantially lower percentage of tax dollars to
achieve it. [OECD data for 1992.]
Only the public sectors of Iceland, Canada, New Zealand, and Ireland spend more than 4
percent of GDP on in-patient care. [Treatment
is classified as "in-patient" when the recipient is resident or remains
overnight in a hospital or other facility, as opposed to "ambulatory care" where
the patient goes to a facility or office for treatment.]
Canada's 4.3 percent of GDP spent on in-patient care is high when compared with that of
countries such as Australia (2.9%), Germany (2.7%), the U.K. (2.7%), and the U.S. (3.6%). [OECD data for 1992.] These countries are among the technological leaders in the world, providing
quality care in the in-patient setting, and they do so at a lower public cost than Canada.
And Canada's public expenditure exceeds that of most of the OECD countries in other areas
of health care as well. For example, Canada's spending on ambulatory care is triple that
of New Zealand, Norway, or Ireland, without demonstrable differences in the quality of
care being provided. [OECD data for
1990.]
Myth: There are too Many Physicians in Canada and not Enough Other Health
Care Professionals
Canada, with 5.5 percent of total employment composed of health care personnel, employs a
larger percentage of health care workers than the U.K., Italy, or Spain. However, Canada
is not a large employer of health care personnel when compared to Australia, France,
Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the U.S., and other countries (table 3).
Click here to view Table 3: OECD Medical Manpower (1989-92)
Numbers are for personnel actively employed
Canada has more physicians as a percentage of its population (0.22%) than the U.K. (0.15%)
or Japan (0.17%), about the same percentage as New Zealand and the U.S., but less than
Germany (0.32%), Norway (0.32%), and Switzerland (0.3%). [OECD data for 1992.] It
appears that in the developed world, medical considerations such as life expectancy, and
cost considerations such as public expenditure on health care, are not directly related to
the numbers of practising physicians or other health care personnel in any particular
jurisdiction.
Nursing employment figures provide some of the most striking contrasts in the data
reviewed. Canada reports that 1.12 percent of its population are employed as certified
nurses, a figure exceeded only by Norway, Iceland, Finland, and Switzerland. The other G7
countries, however, report nurses as constituting less than 0.8 percent of their
populations. [OECD data for 1988 to
1993.] Furthermore, as table 3 shows, Canada joins
Ireland, Japan, and New Zealand in having nurses constitute more than 40 percent of the
total health care workforce. Other health care professionals whose percentages vary widely
among OECD countries include dentists and pharmacists. Practising dentists range from 0.7
percent of health employment in Mexico to 8.2 percent in Greece. Most of the OECD
countries are in the 1.0 percent to 3.0 percent range, and Canada lies in the middle at
2.2 percent. Pharmacists range from 0.7 percent of health employment in the Netherlands,
to 10.5 percent in Portugal. Germany, Australia, Iceland, the U.K., the U.S., and Canada
all report that practising pharmacists make up between 2.0 and 3.0 percent of health
employment.
Myth: Canadians Overuse Their Health Care System
Information on primary care use is incomplete; there is little internationally comparable
information regarding the use of diagnostic radiology, laboratory, and immunization
services. However, significant information is available for physician use. Patient
contacts with a physician range from a low of 1 contact per person each year in Turkey to
a high of 12.8 visits per person a year in Germany. As figure 3 shows, Canada, with a rate
of 6.9 contacts per person each year, has a considerably lower rate of use than Australia
(9.4), Germany (12.8), Japan (12.9), and Switzerland (11.0), but a higher rate than the
U.S. (5.6) and the U.K. (5.8). New Zealand reports only 3.8 contacts per annum, but this
does not account for patients seen and paid for through the accident compensation
commission, and it includes an estimate for those who pay their doctor's bill privately.
Nevertheless, this figure raises the question of whether the sizable user fee of $30 to
$35 paid by non subsidized patients to general practitioners in New Zealand is a
disincentive for people to visit their doctors-a matter that requires further evaluation.
Despite the information from New Zealand, however, it is apparent that Canadians come in
contact with physicians much less frequently than Australians, Germans, Italians, and
Japanese-at about the same rate as the French and Irish, and slightly more often than the
British and Americans. Arguments that Canadians abuse their health care system by visiting
their doctors too often, and that they must be encouraged to use the system
"properly," are simply not supported by the data.
Click here to view Figure 3: Physician Contacts per
Person, per Annum
Myth: If Hospital Funding is Cut or Left to the Private Sector, Canadians
Will Suffer; Some May Even Die
The average length of stay (ALOS) in acute care hospitals in OECD countries varies from a
low of 4.2 days in Turkey to a high of 12.4 days in Germany. Canada (8.6 days) has a
longer length of stay in acute care hospitals than France (6.5), Sweden (5.5), the U.K.
(5.1), the U.S. (7.1), and Australia (5.0). [OECD data for 1991 to 1993.] In terms
of efficiency, Canada has a bed occupancy rate of 78.6 percent, while Denmark, Belgium,
Ireland, and Germany all have rates in excess of 80 percent. Canada does, however, fare
better than the U.S., which has a bed occupancy rate of 66.2 percent, and the U.K., which
has an occupancy rate of 76.2 (1986 data). OECD bed occupancy figures are not reported for
New Zealand. [OECD data for 1990 to
1993 unless otherwise indicated.]
The preceding comparison of hospital use statistics is important because hospitals account
for approximately 38 percent of expenditures on health care in Canada. Since staffing
hospitals accounts for approximately 75 to 80 percent of their costs, an international
comparison of hospital staffing ratios is also interesting. Here again, there is enormous
variation between countries. Japan has a staff-to-bed ratio of 0.8, while Mexico exceeds
all other countries with a ratio of 6.1 persons per bed. The U.S. has the second-highest
ratio of 3.6 persons per bed, while Canada reports 2.8 staff per bed. [OECD data for 1990 to 1994.] The Japanese have the longest life expectancy, yet they are among
the lowest public money spenders on health care, and provide hospital care with a
staff-to-bed ratio just over one-third that of Canada.
The number of acute care beds per 1,000 population provides another insight into hospital
expenditures (see figure 4). Canada, with 3.9 beds per 1,000 population, has slightly more
than half the number of acute care beds per 1,000 population as Germany and New Zealand,
which both have over 7 beds per 1,000 people. The U.K. (2.2), the U.S. (3.5), and Norway
(3.6) provide hospital services with significantly fewer acute care beds per 1,000
population than Canada. These data, like others, change with time, and British Columbia
presently has under 2.5 beds per 1,000 people.
Click here to view Figure 4: Acute Care Beds per 1,000
Population (1991)
Canada, along with the U.K., Finland, and Turkey, are the only OECD countries that report
private hospital beds as less than 5 percent of the total number of beds. In most
countries, private hospitals play a significant role in the provision of care: Belgium
reports that 61.8 percent of beds are private; Germany, 47.8 percent; France, 36 percent;
the U.S., 81.6 percent; Australia, 39.1 percent; and New Zealand, 35.5 percent. [OECD data for 1989 to 1993.] It must be emphasized that private ownership of hospitals does not
imply that only patients with private insurance are treated in these facilities, but it
does mean that these facilities are managed and run as businesses, with proper accounting
procedures (accrual) and concern for efficiency and profits.
Conclusion
The direction of recent health care reform in Canada shows that the policy makers have
bought into the myths rather than into what the data show. The myths have come to define
the problems that the provinces are attempting to resolve. Their solutions will not be
effective because the problems are ill-defined. Reducing expenditures on health care,
closing hospitals, cutting the number of hospital beds, restricting doctors' billing
numbers, and prohibiting private clinics are unproven "shoot from the hip"
attempts at reform. The OECD data indicate that such measures will not necessarily improve
Canada's health care system. On the other hand, some changes, such as increased
privatization, do not create a threat to health care delivery as is often claimed and more
often believed.
Primary care in Canada
Primary care services are those to which users have direct access without referral from
another provider. Table 4 and figure 5 provide the 1992 figures for the numbers of
professional and technical personnel actively employed in their fields and give some idea
of the diversity of people and skills that go to making up the health care field. These
figures represent total active health care employment and are not broken down between
employment in primary care and employment in other areas. Many people in the categories
listed work almost exclusively in direct contact with the public, and therefore are
primary care workers. These include chiropractors, dentists, opticians, optometrists,
pharmacists, and public health inspectors. Others, such as most nurses, laboratory and
radiation technologists, and respiratory therapists work in hospitals or other secondary
care facilities and come into contact with patients by referral from other health workers.
They, therefore, are part of the secondary or tertiary care environment. Still others who
assist primary care providers see patients by referral but are nevertheless part of the
primary care environment; dental assistants and dental hygienists fall into this category.
Click here to view Table 4: Professional and Technical
Employment (Canada 1992)
Click here to view Figure 5: Canadian Health Occupations
Employing more than 10,000 People
Other health care workers may seldom see patients but are still important providers of
health care. Biomedical engineers and health service executives are representative of this
category. Veterinarians treat animal disease and in so doing play an important health care
role by preventing and controlling the spread of disease through animal vectors. Rabies
(hydrophobia) and hydatids (echinococcus granulosus) are examples of potentially fatal
human illnesses for which veterinarians provide primary control.
Physicians are almost equally divided between generalists who specialize in providing
primary care, and consultants whose practices are confined to discrete and carefully
circumscribed areas of medicine or surgery. The role of the consultants is to provide
advice or technical expertise to help the primary care physicians fulfil their
responsibility for the co-ordination and management of overall patient care. In 1992,
approximately 30,000 Canadian physicians provided primary care and approximately the same
number were consultants who saw patients on referrals from primary care physicians.
Patients who elect to pay their own bills, as opposed to having them paid by the
provincial insurance scheme, can, in theory, proceed directly to a consultant physician at
their own expense. However, most consultants in Canada will not see a patient without a
referral from a primary care physician, regardless of who is paying the bill. This is
because the decision as to what consultant can most appropriately assess and treat a
particular disorder is in itself a complex decision, one often beyond the ken of the
best-informed lay person. For example, the investigation of headache is often performed by
otolaryngologists, ophthalmologists, general internists, neurologists, rheumatologists,
oncologists, and neurosurgeons. However, selecting the particular field of expertise and
the particular individual with the most appropriate knowledge and training to assess a
case is an exquisitely individual matter, and one of substantial importance since the
selection of the appropriate consultant can have a profound effect on the outcome for the
patient. This type of decision making is the domain of the specialist in general medicine,
the family practitioner.
Primary care in Canada is organized in a variety of different ways. Most providers,
including physicians, dentists, opticians, optometrists, chiropractors, veterinarians and
many physiotherapists, establish independent practices, either solo or in some form of
association with one or more of their peers. As in most countries, these individuals or
groups of individuals are generally paid on a fee-for-service basis. In some
circumstances, communities or provincial bodies have established clinics that incorporate
a variety of different health care workers operating under one roof. Payment modalities
are variable in these circumstances, but are often based on hourly or sessional rates. In
some industrial settings, company clinics have been set up to provide on-site primary care
to employees. The nature and extent of care varies greatly according to the circumstances;
Stelco and Dofasco in Hamilton, and the "Big Three" automakers in Ontario offer
examples of different types of primary care provided by industrial employers. Care
providers in these circumstances are normally salaried. In many remote northern
communities, initial primary care is provided by skilled registered nurses who have extra
training in diagnosis and treatment, and who are salaried.
Issues in primary care
The notion exists in some quarters that the root problems in the Canadian health care
system stem from two sources. First, the superabundance of approximately 30,000 primary
care physicians who see too many patients too often for the purpose of increasing their
individual incomes, and second, pharmaceutical companies making enormous profits from the
illness and misery of the sick and disabled. Neither of these concepts withstands
scrutiny.
Earlier we revealed that Canadians come in contact with physicians less often than
Australians, Germans, Italians, and Japanese, about as often as the French and Irish, and
slightly more often than the British and Americans. Yet Australia, Germany, Italy, Japan
and the U.K. all spend proportionally less on health care than Canada, while the U.S.
spends more. These and other data reported above belie the suggestion that the primary
care system in Canada needs to be dismantled and rebuilt. There are ways in which it can
be improved, however, and these will be the focus of a later portion of this document. But
efforts to enhance the present system usually tend to focus on the way primary care
providers are remunerated, and this deserves a brief discussion at this point.
Payment modalities
As noted above, the mechanism for payment of primary providers varies considerably
according to profession, place, local custom, and a variety of intangible factors, and has
been the subject of extensive discussion and debate for many years. Several different
systems exist and each comes with benefits and drawbacks.
Fee-for-service
Under this arrangement, the practitioner is paid a specific fee for each individual
service rendered, and the fee is generally the same regardless of the complexity of, or
time spent on each case. Fees are set by the practitioner, by the applicable professional
organization, by the insurer, or by negotiation between the parties. Proponents of
fee-for-service note that it promotes efficiency in service and provides an incentive for
handling a large number of patients. Critics claim that there is a strong financial
incentive toward a high volume, low density practice which is best described as treating a
large number of patients with little or no illness. It is claimed that there is a strong
financial disincentive to care for patients with complicated and time consuming
complaints. Opticians, optometrists, dentists, chiropractors, veterinarians, physicians,
and many physiotherapists tend to be paid on a fee-for-service basis.
Salary
Some practitioners work on contractual arrangements which may range from time-limited
hourly contracts known as sessional fees to permanent annual salaried positions with
agreed upon sickness, holiday, and pension benefits. Salaries may be supplemented by
performance bonuses, and in permanent positions performance is usually rewarded with
promotion. Proponents of salaried doctors point out that salaried arrangements permit
professional providers to concentrate on the quality of service while liberating them from
the pressure to treat large numbers of relatively healthy individuals in order to maintain
a satisfactory income. Critics claim that salaried provision promotes inefficiency,
laziness, and reduced productivity because of lack of incentives to increase work effort
or quality. Health executives, nurses, laboratory and x-ray technicians, academic
physicians, and many pharmacists are paid on a salaried basis.
Capitation
A capitation system is one in which a provider is paid according to the number of patients
on his or her roster. A primary care physician might provide care for 1,500 to 2,000
patients and be paid a set amount for each patient from which to provide all of the
patient's primary medical care. A practical variation of this approach is known as
"weighted capitation." Here, the funding provided for each patient is weighted
according to his or her age with a higher per capita payment for infants and the elderly,
both of whom require more attention than the age groups in between. Table 5 reveals the
average provincial health care expenditure for 1994 broken down by category of expenditure
and age. Weighted capitation balances, to a degree, the disparity in costs of care at
various ages. This arrangement discourages practitioners from taking only healthy young
adults as patients and, in theory, promotes improved access for those who need more care.
Other factors such as disability and chronic disease can be factored into the equation if
desirable. Proponents of this approach claim that it eliminates the incentive to
overservice, which is said to be inherent in fee-for-service payments, while its opponents
claim that capitation provides an incentive to underservice and not provide necessary
care.
Click here to view Table 5: Per Capita Provincial
Government Health Expenditures by Category of Expenditure and Age (Canada 1994)
Capitation is not used extensively in Canada at this time, but it is seen by many
physicians as a way of enabling them to concentrate their energies on patient care, [W. McArthur, personal communications. This is a
frequent topic of conversation among family practitioners today, with many expressing
interest in moving to capitated remuneration.] and also
as a mechanism for reducing the presently increasing bureaucratic government intervention
in medical practice. The College of Family Physicians of Canada and some provincial
medical associations have been promoting forms of capitation in their proposals for
amending the methods of primary provider remuneration. ["A Discussion Document on Primary Health Care Reform in
Canada," The College of Family Physicians of Canada, Sept. 19, 1995.] On the other hand, government, through the Deputy Ministers of
Health Committee, has been promoting capitation as a means of overcoming perceived
deficiencies in fee-for-service financing. ["A Model For The Reorganization of Primary Care and the Introduction
of Population Based Funding," The Advisory Committee on Health Services, B.C.
Ministry of Health, July 18, 1995.]
One aspect of capitation that is seldom mentioned is that it brings with it rostering of
the patients served. That is, every patient treated under a capitation scheme must be on
the roster of a particular primary care physician and except in special circumstances,
such as absence from the home community, must receive all their primary care from that
doctor. Unless this proviso is included, it would be difficult to see any advantages in a
capitation scheme. However, there is considerable doubt that Canadians, who seem to value
their ability to "doctor shop," are ready to embrace what would probably be seen
as a degree of regimentation not previously encountered in health care in Canada.
Summary
Each payment modality certainly brings with it specific benefits and disadvantages as well
as incentives for certain kinds of behaviour by practitioners and their patients. To date,
no one system has been universally satisfactory in any jurisdiction. In Canada, there
appears to be a growing belief that capitation, or weighted capitation, may solve many of
the health care dilemmas facing Canada. This presupposes that physician payments
constitute a significant problem for health care in Canada, a suggestion that appears to
have little or no factual support. Also, we must remember that the British have paid their
primary care physicians on a capitation basis for nearly 50 years, and this has not been a
panacea for the problems associated with delivery of health care there.
The reality is that altering the mode of payment to primary providers almost certainly
will change the behaviour of those providers, but the results may be rather different from
those anticipated, and not all beneficial. For example, as noted in part I by Margit
Gennser, Swedish doctors are salaried and have little incentive to be productive.
Consequently, they commonly see 12 or fewer patients per day and Swedes have an
extraordinarily low physician contact rate of 2.8 visits per year (see figure 3). Any
change in payment schemes will fail that sees providers dragooned into a situation of
which they neither approve, nor help to create. To be successful, reforms must create
incentives to change.
Another and more attractive alternative to changing payment modalities is to change the
way primary care is funded. In order to do this, funding must be directed to benefit
individual patient care rather than make the individual patient fit into a preconceived
bureaucratic concept of what the patient's needs are. This concept is discussed in greater
detail later.
Pharmaceutical costs
An important aspect of primary care is the administration of drug therapy. In recent
months, there has been considerable publicity regarding the cost of pharmaceuticals. In
British Columbia, a program of reference-based pricing has been introduced in an attempt
to reduce the cost to the taxpayer of publicly funded prescription medicines. Other
provinces are considering similar plans.
The reference-based pricing policy in British Columbia states: "In consultation with
an expert committee, therapeutic guidelines will be established and the best overall drug
product(s) to treat a specific medical condition will be identified. Pharmacare will
reimburse other drugs in the same therapeutic category based on the price of this
reference product." [B.C. Ministry
of Health, Pharmacare Bulletin, Aug. 25, 1995.] On the
surface, this plan is beguilingly attractive. Patients whose pharmaceuticals are
subsidized will be able to obtain, for just the dispensing fee, the drug selected by a
government-appointed committee. The drug selected will be therapeutically equivalent to
others in the category and it will be the least expensive. If the physician believes
another drug is required, he/she has only to fill in the prescribed form and fax it off to
the bureaucracy knowing that the likelihood that it will be approved is 95 percent. If the
doctor's application is not successful, the patient still has the option of paying the
extra cost above that for the government-approved drug and thereby obtaining it as a
privately paid but subsidized item. The B.C. Ministry of Health estimates that this will
result in savings in drug costs of about $30 million annually. [B.C. Ministry of Health, "Pharmacare Initiatives Saving
Money, Improving Services," News Release, November 30, 1995.]
This and similar plans assume, first, that there is a problem to be solved, and second,
that this type of approach is the way to solve it. These assumptions require a closer
look.
Those who claim that there is a problem point to the fact that drug costs have increased
more than other health expenditures over the last 20 years. In 1980, Canadians spent 14.7
percent of their total health care budget on all physician services, and a further 8.4
percent on pharmaceuticals. By 1994, these figures had become 14.2 percent for all
physicians and 12.7 percent for pharmaceuticals dispensed outside hospitals. [Policy and Consultation Branch, Health Canada,
National Health Expenditures 1975-1994, January 1996.]
However, the pharmaceuticals figure does not take into account the approximately $800
million in drugs used in hospitals and paid for in hospital budgets. [Statistics Canada, Hospital Statistics: Preliminary
Annual Report 1992-93, cat. 83-241 annual.] This $800
million represents more than 1 percent of total health care spending; thus, in 1994,
Canadians spent almost as much on pharmaceuticals as for all physician services.
Superficially, it would seem that government, the monopoly provider and purchaser of
health care in Canada, should be concerned about the escalation of costs related to
pharmaceuticals. When examined more closely, however, a different picture emerges. Of all
pharmaceutical spending outside hospitals, the public sector component has increased from
2.7 percent of total health care costs in 1980 to 5.6 percent in 1994. However,
pharmaceutical purchasing by Canadian taxpayers, which in 1994 amounted to $100.14 per
capita, falls well below the OECD average, and seems small when compared with the routine
expenses of day-to-day living. [Ibid.]
Another important fact is that pharmaceuticals have brought an enormous increase in the
capability to fight and control disease. In many cases they have replaced much more
expensive interventions. Thirty years ago, one of the most common procedures performed in
Canadian hospitals was a Vagotomy and Pyloroplasty, an intra-abdominal surgical procedure
designed to relieve the symptoms of peptic ulcer disease. As a result of a number of drugs
that have come on the market this procedure is seldom performed today, and the consequence
is a substantial reduction in costs combined with considerable reduction in patient
suffering and disability. There are many examples of how new drugs have reduced costs, but
these seem to be ignored by those who choose to focus only on the cost of the drugs,
without examining the total picture.
When examined from the viewpoint of the benefits and savings invoked by the introduction
of newer drugs, the incremental increase in taxpayer cost from 2.7 percent of health care
to 5.6 percent seems small. It appears that those who focus on drug costs as a problem in
Canadian health care have picked a very shaky cause on which to focus their efforts.
Moreover, when the full impact of cost containment on drugs is examined closely, a more
disturbing picture appears. William Looney has pointed out that "there is growing
clinical and documentary evidence demonstrating that reforms to cut government exposure to
rising drug costs have an unanticipated adverse impact on the national health services, in
the form of additional specialist referrals and hospitalizations; denial of needed
therapies, particularly for the elderly and other vulnerable groups; deterioration in the
overall quality of medical treatment; increased bureaucratization; and higher costs system
wide." [William Looney, Drug
Budgets: The Hidden Costs of Control. The Impact of European Drug Payment Reform on
Access, Quality and Innovation, Centre for the New Europe, June 1995.] Looney's work is substantiated by other studies, including those of
Soumerai et al., who examined the results in New Hampshire and New Jersey when a cap was
placed on medications available to Medicaid patients in New Hampshire. [S.B. Soumerai, D. Ross-Degnan, J. Avorn, T.J.
McLaughlin, and I. Choodnovskiy, "Effects of Medicaid Drug-Payment Limits on
Admissions to Hospitals and Nursing Homes," New England Journal of Medicine, 1991,
vol. 325, pp. 1,072-77; and "On Squeezing Balloons: Cost Control Fails Again,"
Editorial, New England Journal of Medicine, 1991, vol. 325, pp. 1,099-100.] When the cap was instituted in that state, there was a substantial
increase in admissions to nursing homes and a lesser but still measurable increase in
hospitalization. These figures reversed themselves when the cap was lifted. Furthermore,
conservative calculations revealed that the extra costs created by the cap exceeded any
savings by a significant amount.
There are other solidly based examples of how programs such as reference-based pricing
actually increase the cost of health care substantially. In a recent 13,000-patient health
maintenance organization (HMO) study, seemingly benign measures such as restricting
formularies to generic drugs were shown to create even more expensive health problems. [Susan Horn, Ph.D., P.D. Sharkey, Ph.D., D.M. Tracy,
Ph.D., C.E. Horn, B. James and F. Goodwin, M.D., "Intended and Unintended
Consequences of HMO Cost Containment Strategies: Results from the Managed Care Outcomes
Project," American Journal of Man. Care, Vol. II, No. 3, March 1996, pp. 253-64.] The proponents of such programs usually report the savings realized
in drug costs alone, and seldom if ever report the other costs incurred. Studies conducted
in Arkansas, California, Texas, and Germany have demonstrated that the hidden costs of
reference-based pricing programs greatly exceed any savings. [Dr. R. Robinson, "Economic Models for Evaluating Health Care
Costs," Presentation at The Fraser Institute, March 12, 1996.] There is no reason to believe that the experience in Canada would
be any different. Programs such as those presently functioning in B.C. will likely
increase overall costs and also cause a deterioration in the quality of care available to
patients, particularly the most vulnerable-the frail, the elderly, and low-income
patients.
The focus on containing drug costs has occurred in spite of the lack of evidence
supporting the need for such a measure. Furthermore, the literature indicates that a
narrowly focused drug cost containment policy will not be successful, but will, in all
likelihood, increase the cost to the taxpayer, while resulting in a deterioration in
available care. We will return later to the issue of pharmaceuticals and how they ought to
be managed in a comprehensive reform of the health care system.
The hospital sector
Acute care hospitals consume 38 percent of health care resources, cost $27 billion
annually, and represent the single greatest health care expense. [The Health Services Utilization Group for the
Conference of Federal/Provincial/Territorial Deputy Ministers of Health, "When Less
is Better: Using Canada's Hospitals Efficiently," June 1994; J.N. Lavis and G.M.
Anderson, "Inappropriate Hospital Use in Canada: Definition, Measurement,
Determinants and Policy Implications," Queen's University of Ottawa Economic
Projects, 93-08.] In any
consideration of health care reform it is natural to focus in some detail on this aspect
of spending. But first, how does the system work now?
Control and management of acute care hospitals vary from province to province, but in
general, voluntary, non-profit boards of directors are responsible for supervising,
directing, and controlling the senior management of these facilities. However, in British
Columbia and most other provinces, the boards can operate only within fiscal and
administrative regulations set by government. They can neither build, renovate, nor
operate without government approval. They cannot even sell their property unless the
government agrees. If a board is seen to step out of line, it can be replaced by the
Minister of Health. With variations in approach, this type of control over hospitals is
exercised by provincial governments across Canada, and for this reason most Canadian acute
care hospitals are considered by OECD analysts to be public sector bodies.
Performance measures
Hospital services are measured in various ways. These include such factors as
appropriateness, effectiveness, and efficiency. An appropriate service is one that, on the
best scientific evidence, will improve the health status of the recipient the most and
where the benefits exceed the risks by a wide enough margin to make the service worth
providing. An effective service is one that improves the health status of the recipient.
An efficient service is one that is delivered in the most cost-efficient place at a time
when the effectiveness of the intervention will be optimal. [Ibid.] Other important concepts
are those of utilization, utilization review, and utilization management. Utilization is
the use of services or resources, utilization review is the assessment of the
appropriateness and efficiency of hospital care through review of medical records, and
utilization management is the deliberate action by payers or hospital administrators to
increase the efficiency and effectiveness with which services are provided. [
S.M. Payne, "Identifying
And Managing Inappropriate Hospital Utilization: A Policy Synthesis," Health Serv.
Res. 1987, 22(5), pp. 709-769.]
The most recent OECD comparative data date back to 1991. Though slightly out of date, they
appear to point to specific deficiencies in the Canadian hospital system. Some of these
data, illustrated in table 6, reveal that the majority of OECD countries provide high
quality acute care with a much lower average length of patient stay (ALOS) than do
Canadian hospitals. The number of beds per capita in Canada is higher than in countries
such as the U.K., Ireland, and the U.S., while the number of bed-days per capita is more
than 50 percent higher in Canada than in the U.K., Australia, Sweden, and the United
States. Staff-to-bed ratios show that the number of Canadians required to support each bed
is more than 50 percent higher than in Australia, Ireland, and Switzerland, more than 150
percent higher than in France, and 250 percent higher than in Japan. The number of
registered nurses per bed in Canada is more than 50 percent higher than in Germany and
approximately double the numbers for France and Japan. These data suggest that significant
improvements in efficiency, effectiveness, and utilization are required in the Canadian
hospital sector.
Click here to view Table 6: Average Length of Stay, Beds
per Capita, Hospital Staff per Bed, Nurses per Bed (OECD 1991)
A review of the problems related to the hospital sector in Canada was conducted by the
Health Services Utilization Working Group in its working paper for the 1994 Conference of
Deputy Ministers of Health. [The Health Services Utilization Group for the Conference of
Federal/Prov-incial/Territorial Deputy Ministers of Health, "When Less is Better:
Using Canada's Hospitals Efficiently," June 1994.] This
report largely confirms and expands on the OECD data comparing the situation in Canada
with other countries. There is detailed documentation to show that from 48 percent to 65
percent of acute care patient days are being provided to patients who are not acutely ill.
Half or more of the services-and therefore the costs-provided in acute care hospitals were
either non-essential or could have been provided more efficiently elsewhere. The report
documents examples of inappropriate service, ineffective service, inefficient service, and
inappropriate use. The following is a paraphrased version of some of its findings:
Both Canadian and international studies of hospitalization reveal large proportions of non acute and, therefore, inappropriate admissions and use of patient days in hospitals.
There are large variations in the ways in which hospitals are used; individual physician patterns and practices were the key determinants of over use.
Simply reducing acute care capacity did not eliminate inappropriate service or the risks associated with prolonged stays. It is necessary to introduce utilization review to address these topics.
There are very good, well validated, low cost assessment tools for carrying out utilization review, several of which have been used successfully in Canada.
There are wide variations in medical practice in Canada and the most effective way of dealing with this is the development of clinical practice guidelines.
There are many proven ways of reducing in-patient hospital costs. These include pre-admission clinics, day surgery, same day admitting policies, length of stay targets, discharge planning, and other utilization management initiatives. Short stay units, day care, and "do not admit to hospital" orders that respect individual and family choice, are other commonly used measures for reducing hospital costs.
Diagnostic services such as labs and imaging need to be managed better. Studies have shown a great deal of overcapacity with unrealized potential for centralization and coordination to improve both quality and efficiency in the use of equipment.
The inappropriate use of emergency departments has resulted in less than ideal service for genuine emergencies and inefficiency in the use of expensive resources.
Current fee-for-service physician payment systems appear to result in the provision of more services. Canadian and American studies report a reduction in in-patient use of from 20 percent to 40 percent on the part of physicians paid by other means.
Studies of waiting lists typically reveal failures in prioritization and management rather than insufficient capacity in the system.
Doctors who use the hospitals are responsible for generating most of the costs, but they are not employees and have few incentives to economize, nor do they incur any financial risk or consequences from their patient management decisions. Including physicians in policy formulation, management processes, information systems development, and as genuine management team members eligible for financial rewards and penalties with their contributions is highly desirable.
Rigid job categorization and inflexible education programs supported by the unions provide a substantial barrier to change and improvement. Health care workers of the future will have to be adaptable to changing circumstances. This will require changes in the way health care unions operate.
Public debate and discussion of the issues concerned in health care is essential. At the moment, the knowledge of individual members of the public is restricted to the personal experience of themselves or their family. While important, single-encounter information provides very little insight into the overall aspects of this large and complex system.
Many of the observations and findings brought
forward by the Working Group support and corroborate studies conducted at The Fraser
Institute and elsewhere which appear to indicate that hospitals in Canada, as in many
other countries, are inefficient, overused, and fall short of management standards
acceptable in the private sector. However, it would be unfair and wrong to blame only the
hospitals and those who run them for this incentive-based overuse. These deficiencies
appear to be due, in part, to unnecessary government regulation and control. For example,
some of the problems are an ongoing consequence of the 1950s hospital construction
program, followed by The Hospital and Diagnostic Services Act which effectively enticed
people into hospital for treatment, much of which could have been done as well or better
elsewhere, and at lower cost. The hospitals can hardly be held accountable for the
thousands of frail but otherwise healthy elderly patients who occupy acute care beds
because, in many cases, no other placement potential exists. This situation is exacerbated
by the perverse incentives of the present system. While intuitively it appears that
expenditures could be reduced by reducing the time each patient stays in hospital, the
reality is that admitting and discharging patients quickly is labour intensive and
therefore costly. This gives hospitals a financial incentive to slow turnaround, thereby
increasing length of stay and reducing efficiency and productivity. However, if
appropriate incentives for efficiency existed, there is little doubt that the hospitals
would be more creative in finding appropriate placement for such patients.
Hospital budgeting
A key factor in the huge expense of hospital operation has to do with the way these
insitutions are funded. The report from the Working Group on Hospital Utilization makes 20
recommendations, but it does not go far enough. The missing link is that there is little
incentive for hospitals to implement these measures. The pivotal point in addressing this
issue is the mechanism by which hospitals are financed.
In most countries, privately owned and operated hospitals provide a significant proportion
of care, and have to compete with similar facilities to retain the privilege of serving
their clientele. These private hospitals may receive funds from individual patients or
their insurers (U.S.), the government (U.K.), or both (New Zealand). Since these
facilities operate within a competitive market they have an incentive to institute
internal measures to improve efficiency, effectiveness, and proper use, and in these
circumstances the role of government is restricted to ensuring that taxpayers' money is
targeted toward designated areas of need.
In Canada, 28 percent of all health care funding comes from the private sector. [OECD Health Data, Electronic Version #3.6, released
May 1995.] However, very little of this private sector
money goes toward hospital costs. This is an area in which Canada lags behind most OECD
countries; competitive, privately owned and operated hospitals must be encouraged to
compete for the opportunity to offer service to patients from both the private and public
sectors. This is an essential ingredient for beginning to bring the benefits of
market-driven incentives to secondary care in Canada.
In some countries, government payments to hospitals are based on the population being
served. Each hospital has a population catchment area, and only people from that area are
entitled to treatment. Portability is achieved by arranging for patient billing to be
transferred from catchment area to catchment area. In another model, hospitals are
remunerated on the basis of each patient treated. For example, in the U.S., the individual
patient is often regarded as the primary payer, and either the patient or his insurer is
billed item by item for services rendered. This account is then given to the insurer,
which may be a health maintenance organization (HMO), the government (Medicaid, Medicare),
a private company, or the individual patient, who may be responsible for paying all or
some part of it. Experience shows that this type of itemized accounting produces higher
administrative costs than a monopoly system. Of course, that does not mean that the
overall cost in quality-adjusted terms of a system relying on individual billing will be
higher than a monopoly, government administered system. For the provision of most goods
and services, we rely on the market system to provide competition among suppliers; this
influences the package of quality, availability, and price that is offered to the
consumer. The extra cost of separate billing in these markets is to some degree offset by
the overall efficiencies which result from competition.
In most parts of Canada, hospital funding is not based on the population served, nor is it
dependent on the number of services provided; instead, it is generally calculated on the
basis of the previous year's funding by a system known as "global budgeting"
which does not take into account usual market factors such as the number, type, and
quality of service provided. There is a negotiation around whether the previous year's
budget should be increased, decreased, or maintained-hence the name "global"
budgeting. Usually, there is no discussion about the number of services of each type to be
provided, nor is quality of care discussed. Indeed, some claim that quality of care is not
measurable.
Individuals working in the health care field recount a multiplicity of examples that
reflect the types of deficiencies that come with global budgeting. Consider, for example,
the situation in a British Columbia community hospital where two surgeons performed
identical procedures. One, as a matter of routine, admitted his patients to hospital for
five days, while the other surgeon performed all his procedures on an out-patient basis.
The cost of hospitalization in a community hospital varies greatly, depending on location,
size, and case load, but in general runs between $600 to $750 per patient per day. [Statistics Canada, Hospital Statistics: Preliminary
Annual Report, 1992-93, table 16, pp. 32-3.] Thus, in
the situation described, there was an extraordinary variation in cost to the system
depending on which surgeon performed the operation, but for some time, there was no
examination into whether one surgeon was keeping his patients in the hospital too long, or
whether the other surgeon was releasing his patients too early (which would result in
patient suffering and further costs to the system at a later date). Eventually the matter
was resolved, but if the hospital had been competing with other hospitals for funds, this
fiscal anomaly would likely not have been permitted in the first place.
Global budgeting does not create any meaningful incentive for a hospital to be efficient.
If a budget is not spent in one year the hospital will receive less the next, and is
thereby punished for saving. If something is sold for a profit, the amount of the profit
is deducted from the next year's budget-once again punishment for fiscal prudence.
Labour in the hospital sector-the case of British Columbia
Another critical factor in understanding the cost of running hospitals relates to the
labour sector. The latest available Canadian figures are for 1992-93 and reveal a total of
165,747 public hospital beds employing 395,000 people at a cost of $17.8 billion. [Statistics Canada, Hospital Statistics: Preliminary
Annual Report, 1992-93.] By 1995, this is estimated to
have increased to approximately $21 billion. This figure represents over 73 percent of
total hospital expenditures, a percentage that is much higher in some hospitals and in
some locations. For example, the Vancouver Hospital has a budget of $400 million and
employs 9,000 people who receive 80 percent of the total budget or, on average, over
$35,500 in salary and benefits per person per annum. [L. Bartz, Director, Communications and Public Affairs, Vancouver
Hospital, in the Vancouver Sun, July 15, 1995.] This
amount does not include the money paid to physicians who are, for the most part, paid on a
fee-for-service basis by the Medical Services Commission.
The Seaton Commission on health care in B.C. indicated that hospital workers are paid more
than their counterparts outside the hospital sector and that their wages have outpaced
general wage levels since 1969. The commission drew the following conclusions from these
facts:
Such trends do not, of course, tell us whether nurses' or other hospital workers' wages are too high or too low. . . . It might . . . be argued that wages in hospitals compare favourably with those in similar occupations elsewhere. But perhaps they are also underpaid. [Closer to Home: The Report of the B.C. Royal Commission on Health Care and Costs (1991) pp. B-93.]
Many jobs in hospitals are similar to jobs
performed in other sectors of the economy. The largest overlap of comparable workers is
between the hospital and hotel sectors. Both sectors need food service personnel, laundry
service, housekeeping service, maintenance, and clerks. Many jobs, of course, cannot be
compared directly, such as those in the hospital sector that require specific medical
knowledge: this group includes people such as nurses, technicians, and lab assistants.
Excluding these medically specialized workers from the comparison leaves 18 clearly
comparable occupations. The effect of existing wage differentials between comparable
workers is shown in table 7, using the Royal Columbian Hospital in B.C. as an example.
Even though only 18 occupations are compared, if the Royal Columbian Hospital were to pay
these workers wages comparable to those of their private sector counterparts, it would
save over $2.6 million a year.
Click here to view Table 7: Hospital Employees Union (HEU)
and Local 40 (Greater Vancouver Hotel Union)-Wage Comparisons
This comparison, however, includes only 372 of 766 (medically) non-technical workers at
the Royal Columbian Hospital. Given an average wage differential for the 372 workers
compared of $3.94 an hour, it is possible to extrapolate the potential savings which could
be realized if all the non-technical hospital workers were paid on par with the hotel
workers. Adding the amount for these remaining workers to that calculated for the 18
clearly comparable occupations, total savings for the Royal Columbian Hospital would be
$5.4 million a year, equivalent to about 4 percent of its total annual budget. Other B.C.
hospitals could similarly save 4 percent or more of their annual budgets. Extrapolation
gives us a general sense of the savings to be achieved province-wide. If British Columbia
could save 4 percent of its total annual spending on acute care hospitals in the province,
the savings would be approximately $115 million a year. [Calculations based on expenditures on hospital services in B.C. for
1995/96 of $2.88 billion. B.C. Ministry of Health, "B.C. Hospitals Get Funding
Increase as Clark Redirects Savings to Protect Health Care," News Release, April 9,
1996.]
Most critics of the health care system focus on capping doctors' billings and restricting
entrants into medical school as cost containment measures. The cost of the many other
workers in the health care sector usually goes unmentioned. This has incorrectly placed
much of the blame for increasing health costs on the shoulders of physicians who, as a
group, receive a lower percentage of the health budget than they did 20 years ago.
Summary
In the hospital sector in Canada, the ultimate consumer is the patient, but the patient
has little or no say in what types of services are purchased. The government is the only
major health insurer, the only major purchaser of health services, and government is also
the only supplier of almost all hospital services. This creates a conflict of interest
which would be unacceptable to Canadians in almost any other sector of the service
industry.
It is apparent also that the largest single cost for hospitals is the cost of labour, and
from the evidence presented it seems clear that the wages being paid to hospital workers
are not competitive with those in the private sector. This factor, when combined with the
OECD data which reveal that staff-to-bed ratios are higher in Canada than in many other
prosperous countries, makes it clear that hospital employment and wages are a major target
area for efficiency gains.
Case study-misguided directions for British Columbia
[Unless otherwise indicated, the information
for this case study is derived from Ministry of Health documents prepared to inform the
public about New Directions for a Healthy British Columbia, 1993.]
As noted earlier, many of the changes which have taken place in the health care sector in
Canada, including the introduction of universal health insurance, have taken place for
political rather than medical reasons. Inefficiencies have been built into the system.
These inefficiencies are manifesting themselves in many ways, such as progressively longer
waiting lists, increased costs, limited technology, and limited R&D in Canada. Many
provinces have turned to regionalization and increased decentralization of services as
solutions to the problems of access and cost. In B.C., the response to these escalating
problems was to set up the Seaton Commission on Health Care in 1991, which delivered the
document, New Directions, Closer to Home recommending, among other things, the
regionalization of services.
New Directions, the document, resulted in New Directions, the reform strategy; its purpose
was to change how health is defined, to change how health services are provided, to
promote better health for all British Columbians, to spend limited health dollars in a
more sensible and efficient way, and to give communities and regions more control over the
planning and delivery of health services (closer to home). Doctors and hospitals were to
represent the core of health services, but New Directions was to emphasize such previously
neglected health areas as home care and community health services.
New Directions has admirable objectives for a community-based health care system. It
aspires to ensure that people get the right service at the right time from the most
appropriate provider. For example, community health centres are intended to be responsive
to the specific needs of the community and allow for more "client-centred" care.
As well, links with other health and social services are intended to support the
continuity of comprehensive care. Greater public involvement at the community level is
supposed to allow for the identification of health priorities and the allocation of
available resources in a way that best meets local needs. Effective and efficient use of
resources is meant to be achieved through improved administrative savings and by tying
health expenditures to health outcomes.
New Directions fails in that it neglects to include one important mechanism for ensuring
that "people get the right services at the right time from the most appropriate
provider": the market. The market would communicate the wants of patients to care
providers. The market would allow for competition between providers. Competition would
ensure that providers respond appropriately and adopt the most efficient and effective
methods of delivering health care. Competition would also facilitate technological
advancement, not only in medical devices and procedures, but in the way in which medicine
itself is practised. Until market mechanisms are put in place and the incentive structure
of the medical system is overhauled, any reform is bound to fall short of its intent.
Advantages such as the reduction in hospital waiting lists noted in the U.K. and the
significant increase in surgical throughput observed in New Zealand illustrate the
benefits of introducing market incentives to health care.
The organization of New Directions
Community Health Councils (CHCs) and Regional Health Boards (RHBs) have been created to
aid in planning, managing, and delivering services at the community level. The government
hopes that regionalization will reduce duplication of services and administrative costs.
Twenty RHBs and 85 CHCs have been created, and the roles of these bodies vary across the
province, depending on the sizes of the communities, the health services they provide, and
the wishes of local residents.
CHCs have replaced the separate boards of governance that existed in each community. Their
composition is as follows: one third elected by the public, one third appointed by the
Health Minister, and one third appointed from other elected bodies (e.g. school boards,
municipal councils, etc.). At the moment, the public representatives are people who were
nominated from community steering committees. Elections for these positions are expected
to begin taking place in the fall of 1996.
CHCs are accountable to both their RHB, and the communities they serve. Each CHC
participates in the decision-making process through representation on an RHB. Council
responsibilities are still being phased in, but ultimately, the CHCs will participate in
the planning, co-ordination, and control of community health services such as acute care,
mental health, and continuing care. Over time, they will be responsible for allocating the
funding for most community health services; they will be permitted to enter into contracts
with public and private health providers to deliver some services. They are intended to
ensure that their community has access to core services which meet provincial standards.
RHBs are composed of CHC representatives and Minister of Health appointees. They are
accountable to the community, to populations not represented by a CHC, and to the Minister
of Health. Initially, their role is to plan and co-ordinate regional health services and
determine, with the aid of the CHCs, which services will be provided regionally and which
will be provided at the community level. Eventually, RHBs will receive and allocate to the
CHCs a global budget and, with the Ministry and the municipalities, will plan capital
projects. A large part of their mandate will be to protect the health interests of the
taxpaying public who fund the system.
The Ministry of Health is still the centre of power in the system. It is accountable to
the legislature for the health system in B.C. It provides all the funding, defines the
range of essential services, and sets standards and policies for the equitable provision
of these services. The Ministry will allocate resources to RHBs in accordance with a
funding formula for health programs based on such factors as age, gender, and health
status of the population. It will conduct research and evaluate health services. It will
be responsible for planning, funding, and monitoring tertiary care services, and it will
continue to provide and co-ordinate services that are provincial in nature, such as the
B.C. Centre for Disease Control. It will also continue to directly administer the Medical
Services Plan, the Alternate Payments Plan, and Pharmacare.
How New Directions has not worked
New Directions was supposed to save money for the province and thus the taxpayers. It was
also intended to improve the availability and quality of health services received by
British Columbians. "Overall institutional cost reductions have not been realized,
however, and there are no indications that accessibility to care in B.C. has been improved
as few new community programs have yet materialized." [Murray Martin, President and CEO, Vancouver Hospital, speaking at
Medical Grand Rounds in December 1995.] The failure to
renegotiate health workers' union contracts, and the government decision to merely shift
labour around rather than to examine which types of labour would be most effective in a
regionalized system have constrained the ability to contain health costs and improve
service. CHCs are unable to ensure that their communities' needs are met as their role has
already been changed by the Ministry of Health. Rather than allowing them to possess any
real decision-making power, the Ministry has relegated the CHCs to an advisory role. This
mistake parallels a similar situation in New Zealand which appears to be impeding progress
there also.
Hospitals
In 1995, 123 acute-care hospitals in B.C. received an increase in funds of over $90
million, a 3 to 4 percent increase in the budgets of over half of the hospitals. During
the 1995/96 fiscal year, allocations to hospitals will rise to $2.88 billion, a 2.5
percent increase in funding. Over the past 4 years, $1.25 billion of new provincial
funding has been committed to hospital services. [B.C. Ministry of Health, "B.C. Hospitals Receive Budget Allocations for
1995/96," News Release, May 31, 1995; and "B.C. Hospitals Get Funding Increase
as Clark Redirects Savings to Protect Health Care," News Release, April 19, 1996.] The government has spent a total of $150 million since 1991
building new nursing homes and renovating older ones. [Vancouver Sun, May 30, 1995, p. B4.] In 1995-96, mental health and continuing care facilities will receive funding
increases of 4.5 percent and 8 percent respectively. [Better Health Care News: An Update From the B.C. Ministry of
Health, Spring 1995, p. 3.] The total health budget
will have risen to $6.5 billion by 1995/96, an increase from $6.25 billion spent by the
Ministry of Health in 1994-95, and up from the $6.0 billion it spent in 1993-94. [Public Institutions Division, Statistics Canada,
Provincial and Territorial Expenditure, Financial Management System, January 15, 1996.] Health care spending appears to be flourishing in B.C. with the
occasional exception, such as the closing of the Shaughnessy site of University Hospital.
Its programs and staff, however, have not been cut; they have been absorbed by the
Vancouver Hospital at its two sites, and by community hospitals in the area.
Doctors, nurses, and government
B.C. health providers are discontented. Most vocal in recent months have been the
physicians who feel that they are being completely excluded from the government's
decision-making process. Dr. Victor Dirnfeld, past president of the B.C. Medical
Association (BCMA), has said that "doctors have witnessed other instances when the
Ministry [of Health] has promised to consult with them, and then imposed policies with
little notice-such as the introduction of reference-based prescription drugs." [Vancouver Sun, October 6, 1995, p. B1.]
Doctor and nurses are sparring too. With the move to regionalization, nurses, as
represented by the Registered Nurses Association of B.C., have been advocating community
health centres controlled by nurses rather than doctors. They have also suggested that
nurses should be the first point of contact for patients, given the emphasis being put on
containing the costs of the health care system. They contend that doctors are
"clinging tightly to fee-for-service . . . [you] have to wonder whose interest they
are looking after," while the BCMA contends that the nurses' union is proposing a
role for nurses for which they are not trained. [Globe and Mail, September 28, 1995, pp. A1-2.]
Closer to home
The Ministry has claimed that it is downsizing. What it is actually doing is
transferring-it has transferred approximately 3,200 jobs from the Ministry to the CHCs and
RHBs. The government is extending its influence over health care rather than relinquishing
any power to the regions and communities. The Ministry still "holds the purse
strings"; it has defined the core services that communities must deliver and it has
negotiated the collective labour agreements to which the regions are bound to adhere.
Regionalization is inheriting the problems of uncoordinated planning and financing that
afflicted the "old" health system.
The transfer of problems to the regions rather than their resolution is further
demonstrated by a report released recently by the B.C. Women's Hospital indicating that
women are not being well served by the health system:
The system is too rigid and too tightly bound to the medical model. . . . It doesn't emphasize prevention. It isn't geared to meeting the diverse needs of women from different ethnic backgrounds. It is not accessible enough. [R. Wigod, Vancouver Sun, August 16, 1995, p. A1.]
With its stated goals being "to serve all people equally well, while becoming more responsible and flexible to our changing needs," [B.C. Ministry of Health, New Directions News, September 1994.] New Directions is a failure. Its implementation began years ago and its supposed benefits have yet to be seen. Costs have not been contained; service has not been improved. Perhaps these concerns contributed to the Ministry's recent decision to "put all regionalization activity temporarily on hold." [B.C. Ministry of Health, "New Minister Outlines Priorities for Health," News Release, June 21, 1996.]