II
THE ORIGINS OF INDIVIDUAL RESPONSIBILITY
Power in the Constitution
Constitutionally, the power of the state flows from the Crown and
generally speaking may only be exercised by or on the authority of the
Crown. Parliamentary and cabinet government is a system that has evolved
to ensure that power is exercised responsibly by the Crown and its
advisers.
The powers of the Crown may be divided into two classes, those
deriving from the Crown in Parliament and those deriving from the
prerogative. The powers of the Crown exercised under statute law are
authorized by the law-making authority, which is the Crown in
Parliament. Those deriving from the prerogative find their origins in
the ancient customary powers of the king, which have become part of the
Common Law and (like statutory powers) are subject to the interpretation
of the courts.1 They are,
however, exercised without reference to Parliament.
In theory, under the feudal Crown all power flowed from the
prerogative. The king exercised not only the executive power, but also
what later became the legislative power (principally the authority to
tax and to spend) and through his courts the judicial power.
The history of parliamentary government has been a process of
narrowing the exercise of the prerogative authority by subjecting it
increasingly to the pre-eminence of the statutory authority,
substituting the authority of the Crown in Parliament for the authority
of the Crown alone. This process may aptly be characterized as having
made the Crown responsible to Parliament for the exercise of its power.
The Crown continues to exercise the legislative power, but it can only
do so with the approval of Parliament. Coincidently, although the Crown
continues to preside over the courts, it has been required to exercise
the judicial function through an independent judiciary. These are the
qualities that make the Crown "constitutional", and the means
whereby this has occurred have gradually reduced the Crown’s
prerogative powers and ensured that the residue is subject to judicial
interpretation. It is important to note, however, that throughout the
process authority for the exercise of power has remained with the Crown,
and the exercise of power by the Crown on the advice of responsible
ministers forms the basis of constitutional responsibility for the
exercise of power in the system as we know it today.2
The Responsible Use of Power
The medieval Crown was supposed to provide the customary costs of
government from its hereditary and feudal revenues. There was no system
of taxation, and thus no pecuniary need for the Crown to consult lords
or commoners. Government was minimal in scope, but there was,
nonetheless, a well-defined concept of responsibility according to which
it was the duty of the Crown to provide the governance of the realm, and
from the earliest days the chief men of the realm advised the Crown on
its administration. The notion of the government being provided by the
"King in Council" is as old as the Norman conquest.
War could not, however, be financed from the hereditary revenues, and
the expense of war gave rise to the imposition of extraordinary taxes
over and above the traditional feudal levy. Taxation created tension
between the Crown and the baronage, culminating in the first milestone
of responsible government, Magna Carta, which established that
the prior consent of those to be taxed was necessary before taxes could
be levied by the Crown. By the 13th century the development of society
was such that taxation began to be imposed directly on a class of landed
gentry and burghers that was as articulate as the baronage, and the
principle established by Magna Carta required that they consent
to the levying of taxes. The development of an assembly of commoners for
this purpose completed the essential structure of Parliament as we know
it: the Crown, the Upper House and the Commons.
It was not, however, until the constitutional struggle in the 17th
century that the principal steps were taken that made possible the
responsibility of the "Government" to the House of Commons,
which became clearly distinguishable (if not always upheld) in the
constitution by the close of the 18th century. The struggle between the
commoners and the Crown in the 17th century was qualitatively no
different from that between the Crown and the baronage in the 13th
century: each was pursued to force the Crown to exercise power
responsibly.
The weakening of the baronage during the long period of civil strife
preceding the establishment of the Tudors, was followed by a vigorous
reassertion of the power of the Crown, which climaxed during the reign
of Charles I. The responsibility that had been forced upon the Crown by
the medieval baronage had receded as the power of the baronage declined,
and in the 17th century was cast off in favour of the Stuarts’ belief
in "Divine Right of Kings". By the mid-17th century the
principal restraint on the Crown and the principal source of revenue
were the newly established mercantile and landed gentry classes, who
were the commoners. The imposition on this group of taxation without
consent, and the enforcement of its collection without recourse through
law, precipitated the great struggle between the
Crown and the Commons.3 That struggle
witnessed the ultimate penalty for personal irresponsibility in the use
of power: the execution of a king; and its outcome was to establish the
foundation of the convention of ministerial responsibility before the
House of Commons.
The Origins of Ministerial Responsibility
By the close of the 17th century, more particularly through the Bill
of Rights, the Mutiny Act, and the Act of Settlement,
the Crown’s dependency on the Commons for the imposition of taxes was
embedded in the constitutions.4 The king’s
advisers continued to be appointed by the Crown, but they found it
necessary to work in harmony with the Commons because it exercised
control over the financial and military power of the Crown. If the king’s
ministers, those in charge of the principal offices of state, were to
function successfully, if money was to be granted, they had to get along
with a majority of members of the Commons. Gradually ministers saw the
importance of - and a considerable number, particularly those
with financial responsibilities, profited from - being members of
the House of Commons.
Control over ways and means (taxation) and supply (expenditure)
enabled the House of Commons to hold ministers responsible for their
actions, which is to say that ministers, appointed by the Crown, were
held responsible for the actions they took in the name of the Crown.
This individual responsibility was manifested not only in the accounting
that ministers might be required to give to Parliament, but also in the
impeachment procedures that were used to force the Crown to dismiss a
minister who ceased to enjoy the confidence of Parliament.5
There was little respect for the concept of "the
Government", and ministers entered and left office individually as
the king (occasionally at the behest of Parliament) saw fit.
The ability of the king to pick and choose ministers was
circumscribed by political forces at work in Parliament and among
ministers. The growth of political parties favouring particular groups
of ministers further reduced the exercise of the Crown’s prerogative.
George I, the beneficiary of the Hanoverian Settlement, owed his throne
to the new Whig party, and was constrained to select his ministers from
this group.6 George I had the additional
handicap of speaking little English. The powers of royal patronage were
now increasingly exercised on the advice of the principal Treasury Lord,
who became the first of the king’s ministers. In short, the Hanoverian
Settlement began the process of substituting prime ministerial control
for the king’s control over the selection of ministers.
By the time of the Seven Years War the First Lord of the Treasury had
begun to be known as first or prime ministers. 7 By
the end of the century the prime minister had taken effective control
over the appointment although not necessarily the dismissal of ministers
and some other senior office holders. 8 This
development made possible and was accompanied by the emergence of the
cabinet as a device for co-ordinating the views of ministers in order to
enable them to support one another in the House of Commons. In this way
the critical convention of collective responsibility was added to the
individual responsibility of ministers, which in the 18th century was a
legal matter rendering them liable to impeachment. Individual
responsibility remains the primary legal basis of the system today. The
possibility of impeachment has been replaced by the threat of loss of
office, which usually takes place through voluntary resignation in order
not to invoke the collective responsibility of colleagues that would
result in removal from office of the ministry as a whole.9
Ways And Means, and Supply
The imposition of constitutional responsibility, first on the Crown
and later (in its behalf) on its advisers, came about through the
struggle first of the Lords and later the Commons to force the Crown to
levy taxes only by consent.
During the century that followed the model or first true Parliament
of 1295, it was the practice for grants to the Crown to be made by the
Commons with the advice and assent of the Lords. This practice, like
most matters relating to Parliament, was of somewhat doubtful permanence
given the neglect of that institution during the civil strife of the
15th century and its co-optation to the autocratic tastes of the early
Tudors. The practice was, however, actively reasserted towards the close
of the 16th century and under Charles I it precipitated the great
constitutional crisis of the 17th century. The Bill of Rights and
later the Act of Settlement resolved the responsibility of the
Crown to act in accordance with the law, and in particular the Bill
of Rights established that "levying money for or to the use of
the Crown.... without grant of parliament.... is illegal", and set
in place annual meetings of Parliament that led to a system of annual
grants of money to the Crown. 10
Until the 18th century, the practice had been for Parliament to
approve the levying of a specific tax so that the proceeds could be used
for a particular purpose. Control of the purse (i.e. the permission to
spend, or granting supply) was a consequence rather than the cause of
parliamentary control of taxation. In essence, therefore, parliamentary
control over public spending grew out of the struggle to prevent the
arbitrary imposition of taxation. These circumstances, coupled with the
constitutional principle that because power emanates from the Crown only
the Crown may govern, established that only the Crown could propose a
tax or an expenditure. Erskine May, the foremost authority on the
subject, has put it like this:
The Sovereign, being the executive power, is charged with the
management of all the revenue of the State, and with all payments for
the public service. The Crown, therefore, acting with the advice of its
responsible ministers, makes known to the Commons the pecuniary
necessities of the government; the Commons, in return grant such aids or
supplies as are required to satisfy these demands; and they provide by
taxes, and by the appropriation of other sources of the public income,
the ways and means to meet the supplies which they have granted. Thus
the Crown demands money, the Commons grant it, and the Lords assent to
the grant: but the Commons do not vote money unless it be required by
the Crown; nor do they impose or augment taxes, unless such taxation be
necessary for the public service, as declared by the Crown through its
constitutional advisers. 11
The latter principle was placed among the rules of the Commons at the
beginning of the 18th century.
Following the constitutional watershed of the 17th century, the
constitutional advisers of the Crown became more closely associated with
Parliament until by the mid-18th century they became inseparable from
it. At a time when government was growing, political parties taking more
permanent form, and the Crown was if not always less politically active
certainly more inured to the acceptance of "advice", the
ministry as we now know it began to emerge in the constitution.
Following the passage of the Mutiny Act in 1689 all military
expenditure was made subject to annual votes of supply. The civil
government was in theory provided from the proceeds of the Civil List,
voted to the Crown at the beginning of each reign and renewed without
further reference to Parliament each year until the sovereign’s
demise. In fact, however, there were frequent deficits and corresponding
need for the king’s ministers to seek new supply from the Commons.12
Indeed, Parliament annually appropriated the bulk of public expenditure
throughout the 18th century, although it must be admitted that the
scrutiny of the Commons was cursory and there was a general expectation
that it was up to the Treasury to assure the Commons that spending was
being adequately managed and controlled.13 The
principle of annual appropriations by Parliament was extended to all
civil expenditure in the first part of the 19th century when by stages
the Civil List was reduced to meet only the personal expenses of the
sovereign, and funding for the civil administration was placed on the
same annual basis as that for the military services.
Conclusion
The constitutional history of parliamentary and cabinet government
traces the process of ensuring that individuals who exercise power are
constitutionally responsible. At first the Crown, the source of power in
the system, was held responsible by the great men who were the principal
officers of the realm. Later it was the Commons that sought this role,
and ultimately secured it through holding the Crown accountable by
making its advisers responsible to the House for their exercise of the
Crown's power. Thus the individual power of the king was made
responsible by Magna Carta in the 13th century and by the Bill
of Rights in the 17th century. In the 18th century that power was
placed in commission,14 and the ministers
who exercised it were made responsible individually to the House of
Commons. Our system of parliamentary and cabinet government is,
therefore, based on the constitutional responsibility of ministers to
the elected House of Commons, monarchical government having been
succeeded in the efficient constitution by ministerial government.15
1
See Habsburg’s Laws of
England 14th end., (London, 1974) vol. viii, p. 583
2
For discussion of this
elusive subject see S.A. de Smith, Constitutional and
Administrative Law 2nd end., (London, 1973) pp. 114ff; and Sir
William Anson, The Law and Custom of the Constitution 4th end.,
(Oxford, 1935) vol. ii, pt. i, pp. 17-72.
3
The best-known of these
taxes was Shipmoney, a levy on each county for the provision of
ships for the king's service, and the means of enforcement was the
Star Chamber, which dispensed with the procedures of the courts in
order to place criminal justice in the hands of the king.
4
These measures created
"constitutional monarchy". The Bill of Rights (1689)
established that the law-making authority is the Crown in
Parliament, the Mutiny Act (1689) made the existence of the army
dependent on the annual approval of Parliament, and the Act of
Settlement (1701) inter alla removed the control of justice from
the hands of the king.
5
"Parliament used to
bring Ministers to account by a semijudicial process. The King
could do no wrong in the eyes of the law (unless he was Charles I
or James II) and it was more satisfactory and expedient to attack
his advisers for their evil counsel by charging them with high
crimes and misdemeanours. The Commons were the accusers; the Lords
were the judges; the process was called impeachment. Not only
Ministers but officials and judges accused of corruption, were
impeached; the verdicts were not necessarily a foregone
conclusion. During the course of the 1 8th century votes of
censure against Ministers and Governments gradually replaced the
cumbersome machinery of impeachment; political accountability was
better achieved without a heavy-handed political trial. The last
impeachment was brought in 1805; the procedure has never been
abolished but it is in practice obsolete." It survives in the
United States. See de Smith, Constitutional and Administrative Law
p. 169.
6
The Crown devolved on
the House of Hanover according to the terms of the Act of
Settlement of 1701. When Queen Anne died in 1714, the Tories
straddled the fence between George and the Stuart pretender (James
II's son) whereas the Whigs firmly backed the settlement of the
Crown on George, the Elector of Hanover.
7It was first used as a
term of derision by Walpole’s political opponents during his
long tenure as First Lord of the Treasury from 1721 to 1742.
8
The right of a prime
minister to require the resignation of his colleagues has been
exercised very sparingly. The precedent was established in 1792
when the younger Pitt secured the dismissal of the Lord Chancellor
by informing the King that he must choose between the Lord
Chancellor and himself. It was not until the late 19th century
that the precedent became convention. Today the
"nonfederal" nature of the relationship among ministers
and between ministers and the prime minister is confirmed by the
sparing use of the prime minister’s right to dismiss ministers
and the unhappy consequences that usually follow from the removal
of groups of ministers. See Robert, Lord Blake, The Office of
Prime Minister (Oxford, 1975) pp. 30-39.
9
See Anson, Law and
Custom of the Constitution vol. ii, pt. i, p. 118.
10 See Sir Ivor Jennings,
Parliament 2nd end., (Cambridge, 1969) p. 283.
11
Sir Erskine May, The
Law, Privileges, Proceedings and Usage of Parliament 18th end.,
ed. by Sir Barnett Cocks, (London, 1971) p. 676. (May first
published his book in 1844, and he and later his successors have
kept it up to date.) It should also be noted that any M.P. may
propose a reduction in expenditure.
12
It is worth noting that
the charge of the civil administration on the public purse in the
18th century was at best one-tenth (and often less) of the charge
of the naval and military services.
13
For an excellent account
of the Commons’ relationship with the Treasury during the 18th
and 19th centuries see Henry Roseveare, The Treasury (London,
1969) pp. 88-132. At p. 91, Roseveare cites the apparently typical
views of one M.P. on the subject of accountability in 1775:
"Could any ministers carry on the business of the public if
any gentleman in this House has a right to call for such an
account? It would be impossible...; the public service can never
be advanced by calling for accounts which destroy your confidence
in them." The author of this statement merely recorded that
in partisan circumstances questions of administration are unlikely
to be discussed dispassionately.
14
See below p. 23,
footnote 1, for a discussion of this term.
15
Bagehot distinguished
between two classes of institutions within the constitution:
"...first, those which excite and preserve the reverence of
the population - the dignified parts, if I may so call them; and
next, the efficient parts - those by which it, in fact, works and
rules....The dignified parts of government are those which bring
it force - which attract its motive power. The efficient parts
only employ that power". Walter Bagehot, The English
Constitution 2nd ed. (London, 1896) pp. 4-5. It might be added
that the dignified parts are essential to the operation of the law
of the constitution, whereas the efficient parts reflect practice
and custom in the application of law and convention.
[Previous]
[Table
of Contents] [Next]
|