All material on this site is (c) copyright to the respective authors.   ISSN - 1481-3440

The AnthroGlobe Journal

An initiative to broaden international electronic communication in Anthropology

 

Cross-Cultural Correlates of the Ownership of Private Property:A Summary of Five Studies

Copyright © Floyd W. Rudmin 2006
frudmin@psyk.uit.no

Psychology Department
University of Tromso
Tromsø
Norway N-903

First posted: unknown

Table of Contents

Abstract
Introduction
Method - Archived Data
Method - Identifying Societies
Method - Final Sampling of Societies
Method - Property Measures
Results
Replication
Discussion
References

Tables

Table 1 Summary of the sample of cultures
Table 2 Validity and reliability of private property measures
Table 3 Correlates of private ownership
Table 4 Summary of overlap in samples in five studies
Table 5 Summary of robust correlates of private ownership

Abstract

This is the fifth study of archived holocultural data in a program of cross-cultural research to identify the social institutions and behavioral norms that coincide with private property rights. Using Simmons' 1945 data base of 71 societies, a composite index of private rights for the aged, in conjunction with two other indices of private ownership, correlated (p<.0019) with 46 of Simmons' total 217 variables. Replications across all five studies show private ownership to be a positive correlate with agricultural subsistence, social stratification, social control based on law and religion, large populations and permanent settlements, patriarchal family norms, support of the aged, especially aged men, and economic practices of trade, money, debt, metallurgy, and war. Such results can be used to critique theories of property, for example, those of John Locke and George Mead.

Introduction

The ownership of property is one of the most enduring and widespread topics of social science discourse. From Greek antiquity to the present-day, across the disciplines of political science, anthropology, law, geography, history, sociology, and psychology, debate has focused on the foundation causes of private property, on its natural history and evolution, on its social functions and consequences, and on its justice (Rudmin, 1988; Rudmin, Belk & Furby, 1987; Schlatter, 1951). Much of this debate, beginning with Aristotle's 4th century B.C. survey of 158 circum-Mediterranian societies (Jaffa, 1963), has sought to muster cross-cultural evidence, especially from primitive or "natural" societies. Sometimes this evidence has been mythical, as in the Roman and early Christian accounts of communal ownership during the Golden Age or in the Garden of Eden (Avila, 1983; Schlatter, 1954; Tawney, 1926). Sometimes this has been hypothetical or surmised, as in Renaissance accounts by John of Paris, Fortescue, Hobbes, Locke and others of the origins of private property (Hobbes, 1655/1839; Locke, 1690/1952; Schlatter, 1951). Sometimes ethnographic evidence has been carefully selected to make or refute particular political-economic arguments, a common practice in the writings of such 19th century scholars as Morgan (1878), Marx (1972), Engels (1884/1920), Veblen (1899), and a host of comparative sociologists (Rudmin, 1988; 1995).

Hobhouse, Wheeler and Ginsberg in their 1915 book, The Material Culture and Social Institutions of the Simpler Peoples, challenged these naive and abusive uses of culture in political economic debates:

"Theories of social evolution are readily formed with the aid of some preconceived ideas and a few judiciously selected corroborative facts. The data offered to the theorist by the voluminous results of anthropological inquiry on the one hand, and by the immense record of the history of civilization on the other, are so vast and so various that it must be an unskilled selector who is unable, by giving prominence to the instances which agree and by ignoring those which conflict with his views, to make out a plausible case in support of some general notion of human progress. On the other hand, if theories are easily made, they are also easily confuted by a less friendly use of the same data." (Hobhouse, Wheeler & Ginsberg, 1915, p.1)

Hobhouse et al. argued that large numbers of cultures from around the world should be examined by statistical methods if claims about relationships between political economic variables are to be valid. Their own study coded categorical data from ethnographic and travelogue documents for 642 societies in order to classify societies into 7 stages of subsistence economy, from primitive hunters to advanced agriculturalists, so that graphic correlations might be made of stages of subsistence economy with other socio-economic variables, including private property. Hobhouse, Wheeler and Ginsberg (1915) were thus pioneers in applying sampling, quantification, and statistical inference to debates about private property.

Now, eight decades later, the present program of research seeks to continue their project by re-analyzing archived cross-cultural data bases in order to determine which social institutions and behavioral norms correlate with private ownership. Strict standards of social science methodology are adhered to, including independence of sampled societies, demonstrated validity and reliability of measures, appropriate statistical analyses, conservative significance criteria, and replication. To date, four data bases have been examined:

* Simmons' 1937 sample of 71 societies and 109 variables (Rudmin, 1992a),

* Swanson's 1960 sample of 50 societies and 39 variables (Rudmin, 1992b),

* Murdock's 1967 atlas of 862 societies and 44 variables (Rudmin, 1995), and

* Zelman's 1974 sample of 60 societies and 145 variables (Rudmin, 1996).

Replicated results from these studies will be presented and discussed later. McClelland's 1961 data base of 45 tribal societies has not been included in this list because his measure of individual ownership showed near-zero correlations with other established measures of private ownership and because his sample of cultures included many related societies (Rudmin, 1993). Correlations with private property based on McClelland's data, for example, in Textor's (1967) Cross-Cultural Summary, should be cited with caution.

The purpose of the present study is to examine the variables and data compiled in 1945 by Simmons as an expansion of his 1937 study. In his 1945 book, The Role of the Aged in Primitive Society, Simmons identified 56 variables pertaining to the situation of elderly people in society. Using ethnographic sources, he coded four-point ordinal data for these variables. Data were tabled separately for aged men and aged women. One of the new variables was "Property Rights Including Slaves". This measure of ownership practices is thus available to seek for new correlates of private ownership and to replicate the correlates already identified in the prior four studies.

This study is necessarily post-hoc and observational. Certainly, space is inadequate to review all property theories, and it would be a misrepresentation, in any case, to claim to test a priori hypotheses with archived data. Rather, the goal of this program of research is to establish an empirical "factual" base upon which to criticize property theory and upon which future research might rest with confidence.

Method

Archived Data

Simmons' 1945 study used the same sample of societies examined in his 1937 study. In Table 1, on the left, are the names of the societies as identified by Simmons (1945), along with the amount of data missing for the 109 variables tabulated in 1937 and for the 112 measures (56 variables each measured separately for men and women) tabulated in 1945. The letter "p" indicates that data are missing for the measures of private ownership, which in the 1937 data are variables 28 and 29 measuring ownership of land and of objects, and which in the 1945 data are variables 127 and 128 measuring ownership by aged men and by aged women.

Table 1 Summary of the sample of cultures

Simmons' Sample of Societies

Murdock's 1967 Classification

Name

Missing Data

Culture Cluster

Society Name

1937 1945 Code Name

AFRICAN SOCIETIES

Bushmen 24 62 2 Bushmen Naron
Hottentots 26 62 3 Hottentot Nama
Kafirs (Xosa) 25 58 c 4 Nguni Xhosa
Bakongo 11 75 11 Lower Congo Kongo
Akamba 36 65 e 26 Kenya Highland Kamba
Fan 40 94 35 Fang-Dzem Fang
Dahomi 47 100 p 44 Ewe-Fon Fon
Ashanti 16 69 45 Akan Ashanti
Vai 19 86 e 48 Mende-Temme Vai
Mang-Betu 37 93 c 73 Mangbetu Mangbetu
Shilluk 26 85 76 Fung Shilluk
Lango 16 71 c 80 S. Nilotes Lango

CIRCUM-MEDITERRANEAN SOCIETIES

Tuareg 62 94 c 105 Tuareg Asben
Rwala 27 94 108 Bedouin Arabs Rwala
Berbers 36 68 109 Moroccan Berbers Shluh
Albanians 40 87 115 Albanians Gheg
Norse 29 93 c 122 Scandinavians Iceland
Lapps 49 92 123 Lapps Lapps
Hebrews 34 85 c 137 Jews Hebrews

EAST EURASIAN SOCIETIES

Kazaks 26 92 148 Turkestan Kazak
Mongols 35 95 149 Mongols --------
Yakut 25 60 153 Yakut Yakut
Yukaghir 29 59 154 Yukaghir Yukaghir
Chukchee 14 56 155 Paleo-Siberians Chukchee
Ainu 11 53 c 157 Ainu Ainu
Munda 36 86 176 Munda Hill Bhuiya
Todas 26 79 180 Nilgiri Hills Toda
Veddas 23 78 183 Vedda Vedda
Andamanese 25 71 p 186 Andaman Islands Andaman
Chin 38 94 c 188 Kuki-Chin Chin
Sema Nagas 28 77 191 Naga Sema
Palaung 36 61 193 Palaung-Wa Palaung
Semang 16 p 77 p 204 Semang Semang

INSULAR PACIFIC SOCIETIES

Bontoc Igorot 19 54 e 209 Highland Luzon Bontok
Iban 10 40 212 Borneo Iban
Arunta 55 p 79 p d 230 Cent. Australia Aranda
Dieri 22 63 230 Cent. Australia Dieri
Euahlayi 53 p 67 p 231 S.E.Australia -------
Tasmanians 45 90 p 232 Tasmania Tasmania
Kiwai 9 42 235 Gulf of Papua Kiwai
Mafalu 21 95 240 E. Papuans Mafulu
Trobriands 23 69 256 Massim Trobriand
Banks Islands 24 83 263 Banks Islands Mota
Samoans 16 59 p 274 W. Polynesians Samoans
Maori 23 69 c 275 S. Polynesians Maori

NORTH AMERICAN SOCIETIES

Eskimo, Point Barrow 51 92 p d 279 Cent & E. Eskimo Tareumiut
Eskimo, Polar 15 54 279 Cent & E. Eskimo Polar Eskimo
Eskimo, Lab. 43 67 p d 279 Cent & E. Eskimo Lab. Eskimo
Chippewa 47 p 60 p c 282 Ojibwa Chippewa
Haida 21 77 288 Tlingit-Haida Haida
Kwakiutl 17 73 290 Kwakiutl-Bellacoola Kwakiutl
Pomo 31 75 298 Pomo-Yuki E. Pomo
Kutenai 60 91 312 Kutenai Kutenai
Crow 58 72 315 Upper Missouri Crow
Omaha 23 65 319 Prairie Siouans Omaha
Menomini 53 p 100 p 320 Cent. Algonkians Menomini
Iroquois 23 74 321 Iroquois Iroquois
Yuchi 45 87 p 323 Cherokee-Yuchi Yuchi
Creek 28 59 324 Muskogee Creek
Hopi 43 88 330 W. Pueblos Hopi
Navaho 26 71 331 Navaho Navaho
Seri 39 84 334 Seri Seri
Aztecs 13 65 c 341 Aztec Aztec

SOUTH AMERICAN SOCIETIES

Arawak 40 78 368 Coastal Arawak Locono
Witoto 17 66 379 Witoto Witoto
Jivaro 59 84 p 380 Jivaro Jivaro
Incas 63 87 p 386 Highland Peru Inca
Araucanians 26 80 388 Araucanians Mapuche
Yahgan 43 p 87 p 390 Yahgan Yaghan
Abipones 50 94 p 392 Guaycuru Abipon
Lengua 26 61 393 Mascoi Lengua

Legend:

c = corrected data from Ethnology (1967-1971).
d = deleted because redundant sampling of culture cluster.
e = Ethnology (1962-1971) is sole source of data.
p = private property measures have missing data. 

On the right side in Table 1 are the names and identification codes for the same 71 societies according to Murdock's (1967) Ethnographic Atlas. In Murdock's categorization scheme, the culture cluster code numbers and names identify societies that are related by common derivation or by prolonged and intimate contact. Holocultural samples should avoid multiple representations of the same culture clusters. Within each culture cluster, the specific society is identified by name on the far right in Table 1.

Murdock's reports for these societies are mostly found in his bound 1967 Ethnographic Atlas, which was based on 21 installments published in the journal Ethnology between 1962 and 1967, covering a total of 1,264 cultures. Murdock had encouraged the anthropological community to criticize and correct his codings, and these corrigenda were published in Ethnology as they became available. The bound 1967 Atlas reported on the 862 societies with the most complete data on 44 selected topics and included all corrections to date. However, between 1967 and 1971, corrections and completions of missing values continued to be published in Ethnology (Murdock & Spoehr, 1967; 1968a; 1968b; 1968c, Brudner, Murdock, Schorr, Spoehr & Tuden, 1971). In Table 1, a letter "c" in front of Murdock's cluster numbers indicates that Murdock's 1967 Atlas data were corrected based on subsequent reports in Ethnology. A letter "e" indicates that the society had been omitted from the 1967 Atlas and that data therefore came entirely from tabulations in Ethnology.

Identifying Societies

For the most part, Simmons' names for the societies in his sample were easily matched to corresponding names in Murdock's Atlas. However, for seven of Simmons' societies (Bushmen, Tuareg, Berbers, Mongols, Munda, Pomo, and Awawak), Simmons' names corresponded to the names of culture clusters comprised of several societies, and it was necessary to use arbitrary criteria to match Simmons' societies with specific cultures within these clusters. Simmons' 1945 monograph, unlike his earlier 1937 report upon which Rudmin's 1992 study was based, included an "Index of Tribes", a "Bibliography" of ethnographic source materials, and footnotes linking tribes to bibliographic sources. Thus, comparing Simmons' 1937 and 1945 reports, the latter provided more information upon which to match Simmons' societies to those tabulated in Murdock's Ethnographic Atlas.

Re-examining Rudmin's (1992a) earlier matching of Simmons' 1937 data and Murdock's data, it seems that Simmons' Bushmen had been correctly identified to be the Naron, according to the title of Bleek's (1928) ethnography cited by Simmons. The Berbers had been correctly identified to be the Shluh Berbers of the Grand Atlas Mountains in Morocco, according to Simmons' and Murdock's mutual citation of Ubach and Rackow (1923) as an ethnographic source. Simmons' Munda also seem to have been correctly matched to Murdock's Hill Bhuiya, since both data bases refer to the ethnographic work of Sarat Chandra Roy (1912; 1935), whose name was miscited by Simmons as C.R. Sarat and by Murdock as S.C. Ray. Finally, Simmons' Pomo had been correctly identified to be the Eastern Pomo, according to Simmons' and Murdock's mutual citation of Loeb (1926) as an ethnographic source.

However, some corrections of Rudmin's earlier (1992a) matching of Simmons' and Murdock's society listings are necessary. Simmons' Tuareg are not the Ahaggaren Tuareg as reported earlier, but the Asben Tuareg, according to Simmons' and Murdock's mutual citation of the ethnographic report of Lord Rodd (1926), who is also identified in bibliographic references as F.J. Rennell. Simmons' Mongols are not the Monguor located near the Tibetan border. According to Simmons' (1945) citations of Carruthers (1913), the data come from northwestern Mongolia and refer to the Altai Kalmucks, for whom Murdock (1967) has no corresponding data. Finally, Simmons' Arawak are not the interior Wapishana Arawak from southern Venezuela, but a coastal Arawak people. This is deduced from Menezes' (1977) report that one of Simmons' ethnographers, Roth (1908; 1916; 1922), studied Arawaks in Pomeroon near the coast. Thus, the best match for Simmons' Arawak would be the Locono from Murdock's Coastal Arawak cluster.

Comparing Rudmin's earlier (1992a) report and the present one, Simmons' data for the Tuareg and the Arawak are more correctly matched with Murdock's data in the present study, and Simmons' Mongols will join the Euahlayi in standing without any comparison group in Murdock's data base. These changes, of course, would have some effects on the results of Rudmin's 1992 analysis of Simmons' data. Of the correlations computed to compare Simmons' and Murdock's property measures for validity, the only two changes showed slightly stronger correlations when using the correctly matched data. Of the correlations computed to show the significant relationships between ownership and other societal practices, 24 became stronger, and only 8 moved in the null direction towards r=0.00. The largest change occurred with the correlation of Simmons' measure of "Use of Grain for Food" with Murdock's measure of land ownership, improving from r=.39 (n=48, p<.01) to a corrected value of r=.43 (n=47, p<.001). The only important consequence of these changes was the new inclusion of Simmons' variable 14, "Mining and Smelting of Metals", as a significant correlate of private ownership.

Final Sampling of Societies

As shown in Table 1 by the letter "d", three societies were deleted from Simmons' sample because they were redundant of sampled culture clusters: the Arunta, also known as the Aranda, were a duplicate sample of the Central Australia culture cluster, and the Point Barrow Eskimo and the Labrador Eskimo were duplicate samples of the Central and Eastern Eskimo culture cluster. As shown in Table 1, these deleted societies had more missing data than did the Dieri and the Polar Eskimo societies which were retained to represent their respective culture clusters.

Also shown in Table 1, five societies were effectively deleted because they had missing data for all of Simmons' measures of ownership. These were the Semang, the Euahlayi, the Chippewa, the Menomini, and the Yahgan. Thus, the effective sample for the present study consisted of 63 independent societies, only one of which, the Mongols, was without representation in Murdock's data base.

Property Measures

The index of private ownership developed for this study consisted of the disjunctive summation of Simmons' variables 127 and 128. These are measures of "Property Rights Including Slaves", coded separately for aged men and aged women. As with his other measures, Simmons used a four-point ordinal scale to summarize information from the ethnographic source materials:

0 = "absence or non-appearance of the trait, when definitely indicated in the sources";

1 = "incipient presence, slight elaboration, or cultural unimportance of the trait";

2 = "presence without dominance, moderate elaboration, or intermediate importance";

3 = "dominance, marked elaboration, or strong social importance of the trait".

The two gender-specified measures of private ownership, variables 127 and 128, showed slightly negative Kendall correlations with one another (r= -.07, n=30, p=.34). Hence, they could not be simply summed to create a composite index of private ownership. Rather, they were summed disjunctively. That is, the higher of the two values was taken as the measure of the degree to which a society allows at least some aged people to have private property. How property rights are distributed between aged men and aged women is less important for the present study than whether or not someone in the society has property rights. As shown in Table 2, the validity of this composite index of private property is demonstrated by its relatively strong positive correlations with indices of private ownership computed for other studies.

Table 2 Validity and reliability of private property measures;
Kendal correlations of variables and indices

Ownership measures for samples examined

Zelman (1974)

Murdock (1967)

Swanson (1960)

Simmons (1945)

Simmons (1937)

Simmons (1937) Index of land AND objects r=.38 r=.49 r=.25 r=.55 M=.45
n=17 n=56 n=7 n=55 n=51
p=.04 p<.001 p=.24 p<.001 p<.001
Simmons (1945) Index of Ownership by Aged Men OR Aged Women r=.74 r=.62 r=.24

n.a.

 
n=14 n=50 n=7    
p<.01 p<.001 p=.26    
Swanson (1960/ 1966) Measure of Ownership of Economically Significant Property r=.22 r=.46

n.a.

   
n=12 n=43      
p=.20 p=.001      
Murdock (1967) Index of Inheritance of Land AND Moveables r=.61 M=.57      
n=52 n=53      
p<.001 p<.001      
Zelman (1974)  Index of [Ownership AND Inheritance of Land]/2 AND Ownership of Domestic Animals M=.26        
n=50        
p=.02        

Legend:

M = Mean correlation between variables in an index.
n.a.= not applicable.

As was done in earlier studies, conservative, conjunctive criteria were used to determine whether or not a variable was a statistically significant correlate of private ownership. This required that other indices of ownership be available. From Simmons' 1937 data base, his measures of private property in land and in objects were summed to produce a second composite index of private ownership. As shown in Table 2, the two measures contributing to this index were positively correlated, attesting to the reliability of the index, and the correlations with other measures of private property were all positive, attesting to the validity of the index. A similar summation of Murdock's (1967) measures of inheritance of land and of movables produced a third index which also showed positive correlations, displayed in Table 2, attesting to reliability and validity.

Thus, 63 independent societies and three composite indices of private ownership were available for computing correlation coefficients with the remaining 217 of Simmons' variables: 107 from his 1937 study and 110 from his 1945 study. These are all listed in Table 3, using Simmons' category headings, numeric codes, and descriptive labels.

Results

For a cultural norm or social institution to be identified as a correlate of private ownership in this study, the following conjunctive significance criteria needed to be satisfied: a) correlations of the same sign with all three available indices of private property, and b) at least two of the three correlations large enough to reach statistical significance (p<.05). The binomial probability of three correlation coefficients having the same sign is p=.25. The probability of two of three correlation coefficients reaching statistical significance is p=.05 X .05 = .0025, times the three ways of choosing two of three, which yields p=.0075. To this must be added the remote probability of all three coefficients being statistically significant, which yields p=.0075 + .000125 = .007625. Because the sign of a correlation is independent of its magnitude, the statistical significance level using the two conjunctive criteria is p=.25 X .007625, which is p<.0019. With 217 variables to be examined for correlation with private ownership in this study, and with a significance criterion of p<.0019, it is unlikely that even one variable would be falsely identified as a correlate of private ownership due to random patterns in the data.

Because the data were ordinal, the Kendall correlation was preferred to the Pearson correlation. Because correlation coefficients for the three indices of ownership were expected to have the same sign, one-tailed probability estimates were used. The significant correlates of private ownership are noted in Table 3 by the mark # on the left. Of the 217 measures examined, 46 met the conjunctive significance criteria employed here. Included among these were 20 of the 22 correlates of private ownership identified in the earlier study (Rudmin, 1992a) of Simmons' 1937 data. The two exceptions were variable 65, "Marriage by Capture", and variable 93, "Exposure of the Dying." These each produced correlations of the appropriate sign, but each had only one of three correlations achieve significance.

It should also be noted that 30 of the 110 variables defined by Simmons for his 1945 study had fewer than 10 societies available for computing correlations with the composite measures of private ownership. Thus, many of Simmons' variables have not had the opportunity here to be properly tested as correlates of private ownership.

Table 3 Correlates of private ownership

Simmons (1937) Ownership of Land and Objects Simmons (1945) Ownership by the Aged Murdock (1967) Inheritance of Land and Objects

r

n

r

n

r

n

HABITAT, MAINTENANCE AND ECONOMY

#1  Permanency of Residence .25* 63 .33* 35 .49* 55
2 Group Life, not Atomism .11 62 .11 55 .33* 57
#3 Durability of Dwellings .24* 63 .22* 55 .37* 58
4 Communal Houses .12 54 -.10 48 -.01 49
5 Separate Men's House .21* 49 .20 44 .20 44
#6 Collection -.37* 46 -.28* 41 -.47* 42
#7 Hunting -.29* 62 -.37* 55 -.33* 57
#8 Fishing -.21* 56 -.30* 51 -.16 51
9 Herding .13 62 .30* 54 .14 57
#10 Agriculture .30* 63 .30* 55 .65* 50
#11 Use of Grain for Food .22* 59 .31* 52 .48* 54
#12 Constancy of Food Supply .12 60 .30* 53 .30* 55
#13 Domesticated Animals .27* 61 .15 53* .36* 56
#14 Mining and Smelting Metal .16 54 .29* 47 .28* 50
#15 Metals Imported .20* 50 .32* 45 .32* 46
16 Pottery .16 58 .12 51 .24* 45
17 Basketry .13 51 .14 45 .27* 46
18 Weaving .11 56 .10 48 .33* 51
19 Bark Cloth .05 46 -.01 41 .25* 42
20 Use of Bow and Arrow .03 57 -.10 49 .00 53
21 Use of Spear-Thrower .16 41 .09 37 .12 37
22 Use of Blow Gun .10 44 -.09 38 .07 39
#23 Slavery .21* 55 .27* 49 .42* 51
#24 Debt Relations .39* 38 .55* 37 .41* 34
#25 Trade .27* 61 .18 55 .39* 57
#26 Money or Exchange medium .38* 55 .37* 49 .40* 51
#27 Communal Land Ownership -.48* 49 -.33* 43 -.27* 47
#30 Communal Sharing of Food -.32* 41 -.26* 37 -.32* 38
POLITICAL AND SOCIAL ORGANISATION
#31 Power Vested in Chief .14 62 .26* 55 .43* 58
32 Gov. by General Assembly -.20 33 -.11 30 -.14 30
#33 Gov. by Restricted Council .16 53 .27* 47 .31* 48
34 Women influence Government .09 46 -.07 41 .05 42
35 Secret Societies .14 34 .18 33 .16 32
#36 Prevalence of Warfare .15 62 .22* 54 .32* 57
37 Practice of Blood Revenge .04 42 .14 37 -.06 38
#38 Codified Laws .33* 51 .41* 45 .47* 47
39 Group Guilt for Crimes .02 37 .13 34 -.04 34
#40 Authority of Judges .30* 49 .34* 44 .50* 46
#41 Fines Paid to Judges .22 20 .37* 18 .40* 21
42 Matrilocal Residence -.17 48 -.18 44 -.18 43
#43 Patrilocal Residence .36* 59 .34* 53 .17 54
44 Matrilineal Descent -.03 43 -.16 39 .06 39
45 Patrilineal Descent .11 47 .13 42 -.01 43
46 Matrilineal Inheritance .07 41 .05 39 .14 38
#47 Patrilineal Inheritance .24* 57 .29* 51 .13 53
48 Matrilineal Successiom -.05 32 -.17 30 .06 28
49 Patrilineal Succession .13 51 .14 46 .09 46
50 Matripotestal Authority -.08 29 -.24 28 .03 28
51 Patripotestal Authority .08 52 .02 47 -.21 49
52 Avunculate .16 36 .05 34 .18 33
53 Wife Owns Dwelling -.09 41 .07 39 .04 37
54 Age-Grades .10 21 .09 18 .07 18
#55 Castes and Classes .37* 44 .51* 38 .41* 40
#56 Plutocracy .46* 52 .48* 49 .48* 49
57 Exogamy re Kin Group .11 55 .23* 48 .17 50
58 Exogamy re Local Group -.31* 23 -13 .21 -.05 21
59 Group Marriage .06 50 -.09 46 -.20 45
#60 Polyandry -.17 53 -.25* 49 -.32* 49
61 Polygyny .08 61 .05 54 .05 56
62 Monogamy -.03 55 -.03 49 -.23* 51
63 Child Betrothal -.14 35 -.17 31 -.08 31
64 Arranged Marriage .15 60 .12 52 .08 55
65 Marriage by Capture -.14 49 -.15 45 -.32* 45
66 Brideprice .10 60 .26* 55 .07 55
#67 Dowry .21* 43 .39* 42 .30* 39
68 Wife-Lending .05 42 .21 38 -.16 40
69 Remarriage of Widow -.02 56 -.01 50 -.15 52
70 Levirate .29* 45 .16 41 .03 42
71 Funeral Suttees .01 59 .11 52 .22* 53
72 Divorce Difficult for Women .10 53 .25* 47 .01 50
73 Divorce Difficult for Men .04 55 .16 49 .16 51
74 Inferiority of Women .00 55 .15 50 -.02 51
75 Uncleanliness of Women .08 46 .02 42 .21 41
76 Sex Restrictions for Wife .15 56 .10 50 .23* 51
77 Mother-in-Law Avoidance -.05 27 -.07 26 .04 28
78 Primogeniture .08 42 .25* 39 .07 40
#79 Scalps, Heads as Trophies .34* 26 .37* 20 .44* 23
80 Property Rights in Women .15 34 .16 32 .22 32

BELIEFS AND PRACTICES

#81 Organized Priesthood .14 52 .25* 47 .22* 47
82 Shamanism -.04 63 -.08 55 -.01 58
83 Ancestor Worship .06 34 -.07 33 .05 33
#84 Ceremonies and Rituals .29* 53 .37* 49 .34* 49
85 Legendary Heroes .22* 48 .21 42 .16 44
86 Legendary Heroines -.15 34 -.08 32 .10 31
87 Human Sacrifice .15 35 .24 31 .33* 31
88 Totemism .07 36 .22 31 .27* 33
89 Fetishism .54* 21 .32 18 .28 20
90 Cannibalism -.03 39 -.06 35 .14 35
91 Reincarnation .03 15 -.02 12 .36 13
92 Intensity of Ghost Fear .12 56 -.01 49 .15 51
93 Exposure of the Dying -.29* 41 -.25 38 -.20 36
#94 Abandon Houses of the Dead -.38* 46 -.48* 40 -.56* 42
95 Grave Escort .09 51 .10 44 .26* 46
96 Grave Goods -.16 56 -.24* 50 -.16 51
97 Mortuary Ceremonies .11 55 .08 48 .19 50
98 Attractive Afterlife -.01 52 .02 46 .13 49
#99 Belief in Natural Death .29* 43 .31* 39 .29* 38
100 Circumcision .13 26 -.01 22 .24 25
101 Infanticide -.12 40 -.34* 36 -.18 37
102 Picture Writing -.04 14 .31 11 .22 14
103 Written Language .13 39 .29* 36 .18 35
104 Couvade .03 22 -.30 20 -.21 18
105 Transmigration .40 10 .44 10 -.11 10
106 Phallicism -1.00 4 ---- 3 ---- 4
107 Prefer Male Children .09 36 .01 32 -.08 33
108 Prefer Female Children -.13 35 -.05 32 -.04 32
109 First Wife Preferred Status .56* 12 -.03 12 .04 11

PARTICIPATION OF THE AGED

121 Chiefs                                    Men -.07 55 .20 48 -.03 50
                                               Women -.10 29 -.21 27 -.17 28
123 Council of Elders                   Men .12 52 .16 47 .12 47
                                               Women -.04 22 -.02 19 .24 20
125 Judge and Discipline              Men  -.03 38 .22 37 .12 36
                                               Women -.33 12 -.28 12 -.17 11
#129 Traders                                 Men .60* 20 .74* 20 .48* 18
                                               Women .20 6 .50 6 .62 5
131 Officials in Clubs                   Men .27 17 .24 17 .10 17
                                               Women .19 10 .37 10 .35 9
#133 Family Rights                       Men .31* 51 .34* 46 .20 48
                                               Women .09 38 .29 36 .15 34
135 Marry Young Mates                Men -.08 39 -.08 35 .03 35
                                               Women -.27 20 -.34 19 .03 20
137 Aid Pregnancies                      Men ----- 0 ----- 0 ----- 0
                                               Women .24 4 1.00 3 .00 3
139 Aid Childbirths                       Men -.16 22 -.10 20 .40* 20
                                               Women .08 41 -.05 38 .02 36
141 Educate, Care Young              Men .01 35 -.06 3 -.28 31
                                               Women -.02 32 -.07 .28 -.22 27
143 Initiate Young                         Men   .15 21 -.07 18 -.23 19
                                               Women -.08 17 -.21 16 -.18 13
145 Aid Weddings                        Men .24 31 .19 29 -.08 30
                                               Women .27 19 .00 18 -.03 18
147 Aid Funerals                           Men .15 22 .10 21 .26 21
                                               Women .05 24 .13 22 .01 21
149 Priestly Services                     Men .19 31 -.19 27 .07 28
                                               Women .26 13 .44 12 .55 9
151 Prayer, Asceticism                  Men .62 5 ----- 5 ----- 5
                                               Women ----- 2 ----- 2 ----- 2
153 Practice Shamanism                Men -.26* 51 -.13 45 -.21 47
                                               Women .13 41 .08 37 -.22 37
155 Take Taboo Risks                   Men -.19 10 .13 10 .05 9
                                               Women .17 5 .25 5 ----- 3
157 Magic Powers                         Men -.18 18 -.34 17 -.28 14
                                               Women -.22 7 -.21 6 ----- 3
159 Treat Disease                          Men .27 16 .61* 13 .43 14
                                               Women .31 13 .47 10 .24 11
161 Decorators                              Men -.50 3 ----- 2 -.50 3
                                               Women -.05 8 .00 6 -.47 7
#163 Aid Agriculture                       Men .51* 17 .70* 15 .58* 16
#                                              Women .42* 19 .60* 17 .86* 16
165 Aid Hunting                          Men -.24 16 -.08 14 .15 14
                                               Women .32 6 .29 5 .00 5
167 Aid Herding                           Men .23 14 .39 14 .20 13
                                               Women .41 12 .52* 12 .26 10
169 Aid Collecting                        Men .00 3 ----- 2 .50 3
                                               Women  -.82 4 -1.00 2 -.58 4
171 Aid Housework                      Men -.20 10 -.18 8 -.23 9
                                               Women .06 29 .01 24 .06 24
173 Make Toys and Tools             Men -.03 10 -.15 10 -.37 11
#                                              Women .57 5 .80* 5 .80* 5
175 Expert in Crafts                      Men .02 23 -.25 21 .12 22
                                               Women  -.36 7 -.47 6 -.53 5
177 Oral Repository                      Men .01 47 .15 43 -.11 42
                                               Women -.24 23 -.23 23 -.40* 20
179 Suicide                                   Men .10 16 -.28 15 -.04 15
                                               Women -.27 15 -.45* 14 .22 14
#181 Lead Festivities                    Men .27* 37 .33* 30 .22 24
#                                              Women .28* 27 .49* 23 .27 23
183 Defend Status Quo                 Men -.59 7 ----- 5 .63 6
                                               Women 1.00 3 ----- 2 ----- 2
185 Ostentation                             Men .32 14 .47 12 .33 13
                                               Women .00 10 .21 10 .29 9
187 Show Strength                        Men ----- 2 ----- 2 ----- 1
                                               Women ----- 2 ----- 2 ----- 2

TREATMENT OF THE AGED

#191 Respected, Feared                 Men .35* 56 .46* 50 .21 52
                                                Women .09 46 .24* 41 .12 42
193 Community Support                Men -.02 28 .20 25 -.20 23
                                                Women -.03 27 .13 24 -.30 23
#195 Family Support                     Men .27* 53 .54* 47 .45* 48
                                                Women .19 51 .42* 46 .19 46
197 Son-in-Law Support                Men -.21 19 -.02 17 -.18 16
                                                Women -.07 13 -.18 13 -.21 12
199 Fees for Services                    Men -.02 22 -.19 21 -.24 20

                          Women

.10 16 -.12 15 .15 15

#201 Past Merit Rewarded             Men

.28 14 .67* 12 .56* 13

Women

----- 1 ----- 1 ----- 1
203 Food Taboo Privilege             Men .04 27 .31* 25 -.05 23

Women

.28 12 .24 12 .21 10
205 Social Privileges                      Men .21 29 .42* 25 .18 24

Women

-.11 19 .11 16 .00 15
207 In Tales as Daimons                 Men -.16 30 -.23 26 -.22 28

Women

-.26 20 -.43* 18 -.20 19
209 In Tales as Heroes                    Men -.06 32 -.08 27 .18 29

Women

.02 25 -.15 24 -.18 23
211 In Tales as Friendly                 Men .45 7 .73* 7 -.26 7

Women

.13 8 .40 8 .40 8
213 Derided in Stories                   Men .17 6 ----- 5 -.77 4

Women

-.20 8 -.30 7 -.25 5
215 Persecuted as Evil                    Men -.16 17 -.08 15 .29 16

Women

-.01 20 -.10 18 .24 19
#217 Abandoned, Exposed             Men -.42* 33 -.60* 29 -.38* 29

#                                               Women

-.36* 34 -.57* 30 -.33* 30
219 Assaulted, Killed                      Men -.13 36 -.23 32 -.21 33

Women

-.05 36 -.16 32 -.15 33
221 Sacrificed                                Men .21 22 .21 18 -.16 18

Women

.08 22 .15 18 ----- 18
223 Seek Violent Death                  Men .20 14 .41 12 -.03 11

Women

.10 16 .05 14 -.35 13
225 Near Death Favors                   Men .17 22 .20 21 -.02 22

Women

.51 9 .35 9 -.24 10
227 Death Memorials                      Men .50 8 .26 7 .33 8

Women

----- 3 ----- 3 ----- 3
229 Attractive Afterlife                   Men -.03 24 .12 21 .15 23

Women

-.08 16 .00 15 .11 14
231 Cannibalized                            Men -.15 21 -.16 18 -.09 18

Women

-.16 18 -.17 16 -.25 17
233 Beheaded, Scalped                   Men .40 5 ----- 4 .62 5

Women

.53 5 ----- 4 .20 6

Legend: Kendall Correlations # p<.0019; * p<.05

Replication

In the social sciences, every study has its faults and every researcher has his or her biases. Thus, confidence in a claim can only arise from replication, preferably by studies designed with different intentions in mind, with different scholars collecting the data from a variety of ethnographic sources, with different operational definitions for the variables, and with different samples of societies. The present program of research has been very much directed to seeking to establish confidence through replication.

For each of the five cross-cultural studies to date, the variables were defined and the data were collected for a number of different purposes, none of which were to examine property theory per se. Simmons' 1937 study was designed and directed to confirm by quantitative methods the conclusions reached by his mentors Sumner, Keller, and Davie in their 1927 non-quantitative cross-cultural study. Simmons' 1945 study had a very different purpose, to discover if older people in the world's societies had common problems and opportunities in relation to various social norms and institutions. The purpose of Swanson's 1960 study was to explore the functions of beliefs in high gods. Murdock's 1967 Atlas was intended to serve as a general ethnographic data base. Zelman's 1974 cross-cultural study was designed to discover gender roles and power relationships relative to reproduction.

The data for the five studies to date were collected by four different scholars. In the case of Simmons collecting data for two of the studies, there was almost a decade separation between his two projects, and the data took different forms, i.e., in his first study, his codes characterized societies, and in his second study, his codes characterized genders within societies. Thus, any biases in these five studies caused by the authors' intentions should be different for the different authors and studies.

For each of the five cross-cultural studies to date, a different operational definition of private ownership was used. These have already been defined, discussed, and displayed in Table 2, on the left. Simmons' 1937 index measure of ownership was created by summing his 1937 measures of property in land and in objects. Simmons' 1945 index measure of ownership equaled his measure of ownership by aged men or by aged women, which ever was greater. Zelman's index of ownership was created by averaging a measure of land ownership with a measure of land inheritance, and then summing that with a measure of ownership of animals. In some instances, the correlates of private ownership have also been measured by two or more different operational definitions. For example, Simmons (1937), Swanson (1960/1966) and Murdock (1967) each have a measure of how much a society gets its food from agriculture. In every instance, each of these three measures correlated positively with each of the five indices of private ownership. The demonstration of conceptual replication should be cause for further confidence.

Table 4 Summary of overlap in samples in five studies

Simmons

(1937)

N=71

Simmons

(1945)

N=71

Swanson

(1960)

N=50

Murdock

(1967)

N=459

Zelman

(1974)

N=60

Simmons (1937):

(Rudmin 1992a)

n=63 Grand N=510
Simmons (1945):

(This study)

(55) n=55
Swanson (1960):

(Rudmin 1992b)

(7) (7) n=48
Murdock (1967):

(Rudmin 1995)

(30) (33) (31) n=459
Zelmin (1974):

(Rudmin 1996)

(17) (14) (12) (43) n=60

Legend:

N = Number of societies in the sample.
n = Number of sampled societies with property measures.
( ) = Number of societies shared in common by two samples.
Grand N = Number of societies used in all studies to date.

To date, a total of five different samples of societies have been examined. Although the two studies by Simmons used the same sample, the study of Murdock's data employed two mutually exclusive samples. A summary comparison of the different samples of societies used in these studies appears in Table 4. In total, 510 societies have been examined. The numbers in brackets refer to societies common to any two intersecting studies. Murdock's and Zelman's data bases have most overlap, and Simmons' and Swanson's data bases have least overlap. Of the five samples of societies examined to date, a total of 416 societies have appeared uniquely in only one sample, 70 societies have appeared in two samples, 22 societies have appeared in three samples, and only two societies (the Nama and the Iban) have appeared in four samples. No societies have appeared in all five samples. Thus, if only the samples of societies are considered, these studies are not completely independent replications of one another. However, they are independent replications to the degree that the data were collected for different purposes, by different authors, using different operational definitions.

Table 5 Summary of robust correlates of private ownership

Simmons (1937) n=63 Simmons (1945) n=55 Swanson (1960) n=48 Murdock (1967) n=459 Zelman (1974) n=60

SUBSISTENCE PRACTICES

Agriculture s  w  m

C  C  C

s  w  m

C  C  C

s  w  m

c  C  C

s  w  m

C  C  C

s  w  m

c  c  C

Grain Agriculture s  w  m

C  C  c

s  w  m

C  C  c

s  w  m

c  C  c

s  w  m

C  C  C

s  w  m

C  c  C

NOT Collecting s  w  m

C  ?  C

s  w  m

C  ?  C

s  w  m

C  C  C

s  w  m

C  C  C

s  w  m

C  c  C

NOT Hunting s  w  m

C  ?  C

s  w  m

C  ?  C

s  w  m

C  c  C

s  w  m

C  C  C

s  w  m

C  c  C

Large Domestic Animals s  m

C  C

s  m

c  C

s  m

c  C

s  m

C  C

s  m

C  C

NOT Root Crops w  m

c  c

w  m

C  C

w  m

c  c

w  m

c  C

w  m

c  c

Bovine Husbandry m

C

m

C

m

C

m

C

m

C

Plow Cultivation m

C

m

c

m

C

m

C

m

C

Intensive Cultivation m

C

m

C

m

c

m

C

m

C

NOT Communal Food s

C

s

C

s

C

s

C

s

c

Milking Livestock m

c

m

c

m

c

m

C

m

C

Constant Food Supply s

c

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

c

STRATIFICATION AND GENDER ROLES

Classes s  w  m

C  c  C

s  w  m

C  c  C

s  w  m

c  C  C

s  w  m

C  C  C

s  w  m

C  C  C

Slavery s  m

C  c

s  m

C  c

s  m

c  C

s  m

C  C

s  m

C  c

Craft Specialization m

C

m

C

m

c

m

C

m

C

Men do Pottery m

C

m

c

m

c

m

C

m

c

Stratified by Occupation m

c

m

c

m

c

m

C

m

C

Dual Class Stratification m

C

m

c

m

c

m

c

m

C

Educate Sons W>M z

c

z

c

z

c

z

C

z

C

Men do House Building m

c

m

c

m

c

m

C

m

c

SOCIAL CONTROL AND RELIGION

Higher Jurisdictions m

c

m

C

m

C

m

C

m

C

Supernatural Sanctions w

C

w

C

w

C

w

C

w

c

Ceremony and Ritual s

C

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

c

Belief in Natural Death s

C

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

c

Plutocracy s

C

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

c

Codified Laws s

C

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

c

Sovereign Organisation w

c

w

c

w

c

w

C

w

C

Authority of Judges s

C

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

c

Power Vested in Chief s

c

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

C

Government by Council s

c

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

c

Local Jurisdictions m

c

m

C

m

c

m

C

m

c

Organized Priesthood s

c

s

C

s

c

s

c

s

c

COMMUNITY AND ARCHITECTURE

Durable Walls

s  m

C  C

s  m

C  C

s  m

c  C

s  m

C  C

s  m

c  C

Large Population

w  m

C  c

w  m

c  C

w  m

c  C

w  m

C  C

w  m

C  C

Permanent Settlements

s  m

C  C

s  m

C  C

s  m

c  c

s  m

C  C

s  m

c  C

Populous Communities

m

C

m

C

m

c

m

C

m

C

NOT Abandon Homes of Dead

s

C

s

C

s

C

s

C

s

c

Raised House Floors

m

C

m

c

m

c

m

C

m

c

NOT Rounded Roofs

m

C

m

c

m

c

m

C

m

c

Dense Settlements

m

c

m

C

m

c

m

C

m

c

MARRIAGE AND FAMILY PRACTICES

Patrilocal Residence

s  m

C  c

s  m

C  C

s  m

c  c

s  m

c  C

s  m

c  C

NOT Bilateral Descent

m

C

m

C

m

c

m

C

m

C

NOT Uxorilocal Residence

m

c

m

C

m

c

m

C

m

C

Patrilineal Sibs, Clans

m

c

m

c

m

c

m

C

m

C

NOT Virilocal Residence

m

c

m

c

m

c

m

C

m

C

NOT Ambilocal Residence

m

c

m

C

m

c

m

C

m

c

Patrilineal Inheritance

s

C

s

C

s

c

s

c

s

c

NOT Outgroup Intimacy

w

c

w

C

w

c

w

C

w

c

ECONOMIC RELATIONS

Debt Relations

s  w

C  c

s  w

C  c

s  w

C  c

s  w

C  C

s  w

C  c

Warfare

s  z

c  C

s  z

C  C

s  z

c  c

s  z

C  C

s  z

C  c

Trade

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

C

s

C

Money or Exchange Medium

s

C

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

C

Metals Imported

s

C

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

C

Mining and Smelting

s

c

s

C

s

C

s

c

s

c

ROLE OF AGED MEN AND WOMEN

Family Support: Men

s

C

s

C

s

C

s

C

s

C

NOT Abandoned: Women

s

C

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

c

Lead Festivities: Women

s

C

s

C

s

c

s

c

s

C

NOT Abandoned: Men

s

C

s

C

s

c

s

C

s

?

Traders: Men

s

C

s

C

s

c

s

c

s

c

Family Rights: Men

s

C

s

C

s

c

s

c

s

c

Lead Festivities: Men

s

C

s

C

s

?

s

c

s

c

Past Merit Rewarded: Men

s

c

s

C

s

?

s

C

s

c

Legend:

Source of Variables: s=Simmons, w=Swanson, m=Murdock, z=Zelman

Correlations:
C=(positive correlation) and (p<.05). 
c=(positive correlation) but (p>.05).
? = (n<10) and (indeterminate).

Table 5 is a summary display of the robust correlates of private ownership identified in the five studies to date. Robust here means that the expected correlation is evident in every instance it which it is possible to compute a correlation, regardless of who collected the data, for whatever purposes, regardless of how private ownership was operationalized, and regardless of how small and unrepresentative the set of societies available for the computation. Thus, Table 5 may omit variables that might be true correlates of private ownership, but which are not robust.

In Table 5, the data bases for the five studies to date are displayed across the top, along with the number of societies with property measures in each study. For a variable to be listed in Table 5, its correlation with a measure of private ownership must have met strict significance criteria in at least one study. The replicated, robust correlates of private ownership are listed on the left. They are grouped into seven categories and ordered within each category from the most replicated to the least. In order to simplify the table by displaying only positive correlations, each negative correlate of private ownership had "NOT" inserted into its label in order to reverse its meaning and thus transform the negative correlation to a positive one. In other words, Table 5 indicates those social norms and institutions that tend to be present when private ownership is present and absent when private ownership is absent.

An upper case "C" indicates that the correlation was positive and was statistically significant at p<.05. A lower case "c" indicates that the correlation was positive but was not of sufficient magnitude to achieve statistical significance. In the case of Murdock's index of ownership correlating with one of his own measures, an upper case "C" was used only when the correlation coefficients were significant in both samples drawn from Murdock's Atlas, and a lower case "c" was used in the one instance of "Dual Class Stratification" in which the correlation was significant in one sample (r=.22, n=296, p<.001) of Murdock's data but not in the other (r=.13, n=145, p=.06). A question mark (?) indicates that fewer than ten societies were available for the computation and that the results were indeterminate, either because r=0.00 or because one of the measures was invariant. These symbols all refer to Kendall correlation values.

To read Table 5, consider the first entry, "Agriculture." Simmons ("s"), Swanson ("w"), and Murdock ("m") had each defined and coded data for a measure of the degree to which a society engaged in agriculture. A composite measure of ownership of land and objects from Simmons' 1937 study had significant (p<.05), positive Kendall correlations with all three measures of agriculture. Similarly, with Simmons' 1945 data, a composite measure of ownership by aged men or aged women had a significant, positive correlation with all three measures of agriculture. Swanson's 1960 measure of "Ownership of Economically Significant Property" had a positive correlation with all three measures of agriculture, but did not achieve statistical significance with Simmons' measure of agriculture (r=.15, n=8, p=.33). Murdock's composite measure of the inheritance of land and of movables had significant, positive correlations with Simmons' and Swanson's measures of agriculture. Furthermore, Murdock's measure of ownership had significant, positive correlations with his own measure of agriculture for both of the samples drawn from his data (r=.46, n=147, p<.001 and r=.44, n=312, p<.001). Finally, Zelman's composite measure of the ownership and inheritance of land and the ownership of domestic animals had a positive correlation with all three measures of agriculture, but not of sufficient magnitude to achieve significance with Simmons' measures of agriculture (r=.30, n=19, p=.08) nor with Swanson's measure (r=.29, n=12, p=.14). In those instances where statistical significance was not demonstrated, there were simply too few societies available to make statistical significance a reasonable expectation.

Even disregarding the magnitudes of the correlation coefficients and their levels of statistical significance, summary statistical probabilities can be computed from just the signs of the correlations. If the 16 computed correlations between private ownership and agriculture are presumed to be independent of one another, then the binomial probability of achieving 16 positive correlations due to random patterns in the data is p=.0000153. Thus, it is nearly certain that agricultural food sources tend to coincide with private ownership.

Independence means that each of the correlations is free to be either positive or negative, that the sign of one correlation is not constrained by the other correlations. Independence seems a correct presumption since the property measures have been uniquely defined and the data have been uniquely collected, or in the case of Murdock's data, the two samples are exclusive, having no societies in common. However, the presumption of independence might be challenged because the samples for the other studies do have some societies in common. Two societies, the Nama and the Iban, appear in four of the five samples. To examine the effects of non-independent samples on conceptual replication, the Nama and the Iban can be assigned to the Swanson study, which has the smallest sample, and can be deleted from the other studies. A recomputation of the correlations showed that in no instance did the deletion of the Nama and the Iban cause the signs of the correlations reported in Table 5 to change. Thus, the overlap of samples seems not to be responsible for the conceptual replications.

Discussion

The social institutions and behavioral norms listed in Table 5 might be conceived to be "objective observations" of the societal characteristics that tend to co-exist with private property. Each correlation is an "observation", something "seen" by the "observer" who defined the measures, collected the data, and organized them for the computation of correlations. These observations are "objective" in the sense that several observers, whether they know it or not, have agreed that they see the same thing. This agreement exists even though each observer has unique interests and none of them was even "looking" to see property relations.

Thus, Table 5 presents some "facts" about private ownership, to the extent that social science can observe "facts" when casting its eyes around the globe and across numerous cultures. Although the observations have been post hoc, opportunistic, and atheoretical, theories about property should be compatible with these facts where they pertain. Empirical tests of theories need not always be a priori.

For example, John Locke presented his labor theory of property in his Second Treatise on Government in 1690. He argued that it is self-evident that humans naturally own their own bodies, and, therefore, they own their bodies' labor and whatever gets mixed with that labor. Locke imagined that the derivation of ownership from labor was most clearly evident in the hunting and gathering of food by North American native peoples:

"The fruit or venison which nourishes the wild Indian, who knows no enclosure and is still a tenant in common, must be his, and so his, i.e., a part of him. . . He that is nourished by the acorns he picked up under an oak, or the apples he gathered from the trees in the wood, has certainly appropriated them to himself. Nobody can deny but the nourishment is his. . . Thus this law of reason makes the deer that Indian's who has killed it; it is allowed to be his goods who has bestowed his labor upon it, though before it was the common right of every one." (Locke, 1690/1952,pp. 17-19.)

The cross-cultural observations reported in Table 5, however, do not support Locke. Where people do in fact gather acorns and apples, where they do hunt venison, in explicitly those conditions, private ownership tends not to be the norm. To the contrary, hunting and gathering peoples tend not to have private ownership of land or of goods. Typically, they secure their sustenance, not by private rights and not by means of exclusive access to resources, but by rights of sharing and by means of intra-communal and inter-communal access to resources (Gould, 1982; Hayden, 1992a; 1992b; 1993).

Locke's labor theory is one of the most influential and widely discussed theories of property. For example, the 1997 Social Sciences Citation Index (Anon., 1998) shows that his Second Treatise on Government was cited almost 100 times that year. Nevertheless, Locke is wrong. He himself was an ardent empiricist, and it seems likely that he would have acquiesced to the "facts" had he known them. That his theory seemed reasonable at the time, and to subsequent generations of readers, probably relates to the need to justify unequal distributions of property or to the need for whole populations to internalize motivations for work, both of which were issues of the Protestant movements of Locke's day (Aaron, 1972; Schama, 1987; Tawney, 1926; Weber, 1930).

Locke's labor theory might best be salvaged by shifting the focus away from physical labor per se to the expectations that motivate labor. As argued by Bentham and Litwinski (Rudmin, 1990), possession is essentially cognitive and only incidentally physical. Humans naturally have prospective imaginations and acquire and secure objects, information, and interpersonal relationships for their expected future utility. Possessions can be acquired in many ways, including labor, discovery, inheritance, trading, gift, and theft, but in Locke's mental experiment of trying to describe first acts of ownership by an isolated person in primitive conditions, labor seems the only way. The "facts" show, however, that hunting and gathering are not the ideal conditions for predicting the appearance of private property, possibly because the windfall features of these activities, and the relatively short shelf-life of the food acquired, make them not amenable to prospective imagination and norms of possession. In fact, time studies of hunting-gathering peoples show that they labor very little and live a leisurely, though materially simple, lifestyle (Lee, 1968).

In comparison to hunting and gathering, grain agriculture requires permanent settlement near maintained and protected agricultural land, requires seed grain, draft animals, and work implements to be secured for future use, requires intensive, organized labor, and requires that all of this be motivated by reasonable expectations of a harvest that can be stored for future consumption. Agriculture, in comparison to hunting and gathering, yields surpluses that can support large populations, including relatively non-productive groups such as rulers, warriors, priests, and the aged. Private ownership would be predictable in an agricultural society.

This is but one example of how a foundation of facts about private ownership might be used to eliminate incorrect theories. In this case, it was fortuitous that Locke had cast his theory into the context of hunting and gathering, and that cross-cultural data on property norms in hunting and gathering societies are abundantly available. A lesser known theory of property is George Mead's (1982) explanation that one way for the organic community to adjust to strangers and unknown personalities is to adopt abstract, rule-governed norms, such as private ownership. However, one of the robust, positive correlates shown in Table 5 is "NOT Outgroup Intimacy". Thus, Mead is exactly wrong: private property tends to be absent where there is intimate contact with outgroup personalities. Again, it is fortuitous that data were available to test his claim.

The present program of research will continue to examine existing, archived, cross-cultural data bases that have useful measures. However, after those resources have been exhausted, new studies will be commissioned to define variables and to collect new data explicitly to test property theory.

References

Aaron, R.I. (1972). "Locke", in Encyclopaedia Britannica, Vol. 14, pp. 188-193, William Benton, Chicago.

Anon. (1998). Social Sciences Citation Index: 1997, Annual, Part 2, Institute for Scientific Information, Philadelphia.

Avila, c (1983). Ownership: Early Christian Teaching, Sheed and Ward, London.

Bleek, D.F. (1928). The Naron: A Bushman Tribe of the Central Kalahari, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Brudner, L.A., Murdock, G.P., Schoor, T., Spoehr, A. and Tuden, A. (1971). "Ethnographic atlas", Ethnology 10, 122-127.

Carruthers, A.D. (1913). Unknown Mongolia: A Record of Travel and Exploration in Northwest Mongolia and Dzungaaria, Hutchinson, London.

Engels, F. (1920). "The origin of the family, private property, and the state", in The Marx-Engels Reader, 2nd ed., (R.c Tucker, Ed.), pp. 734-759, W.W. Norton, New York. (Originally published in 1884.)

Gould, R.A. (1982). "To have and have not: The ecology of sharing among hunter-gatherers", in Resource Managers: North American and Australian Hunter-Gatherers (N.M. Williams and E.S. Hunn, Eds.), pp. 69-91, Westview Press, Boulder, CO.

Hayden, B. (1992a). "Introduction: Ecology and culture", in A Complex Culture of the British Columbia Plateau (B. Hayden, Ed.), pp. 1-46, University of British Columbia Press, Vancouver.

Hayden, B. (1992b). "Conclusions: Ecology and complex hunter/gatherers", in A Complex Culture of the British Columbia Plateau (B. Hayden, Ed.), pp. 525-563, University of British Columbia Press, Vancouver.

Hayden, B. (1993). Archeology: The Science of Once and Future Things, W.H. Freeman, New York.

Hobbes, T. (1839). "De Corpore Politico, or the Elements of Law", in The English Works of Thomas Hobbes, vol. 4, (W. Molesworth, Ed.), pp. 77-228, John Bohm, London. (Originally published in 1655.)

Hobhouse, L. T., Wheeler, G. and Ginsberg, M. (1915). The Material Culture and Social Institutions of the Simpler Peoples: An Essay in Correlation, Chapman and Hall, London.

Jaffa, H.V. (1963). "Aristotle", in History of Political Philosophy (L. Strauss and J. Cropsey, Eds.), pp. 64-123, Rand McNally, Chicago.

Lee, R.B. (1968). "What hunters do for a living, or, how to make out on scarce resources", in Man the Hunter (R.B. Lee and I. DeVore, Eds.), pp. 30-48, Aldine, Chicago.

Locke, J. (1952). The Second Treatise on Government, Bobbs- Merrill, New York. (Originally published in 1690.)

Loeb, E.M. (1926). "Pomo Folkways", University of California Publications in American Archaeology and Ethnology 24, 149- 409.

Marx, K. (1972). The Ethnological Notebooks of Karl Marx, (L. Krader, Ed. and Trans.), Van Gorgum, Assen.

McClelland, D.c (1961). The Achieving Society, Van Nostrand, New York.

Mead, G.H. (1982). The Individual and the Social Self: The Unpublished Work of George Herbert Mead (D.L. Miller, Ed.), University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Menezes, M.N. (1977). British Policies Toward the Amerindians in British Guiana, 1803-1823, Clarendon, Oxford.

Morgan, L. (1878). Ancient Society, Holt, New York.

Murdock, G.P. (1967). Ethnographic Atlas, University of Pittsburg Press, Pittsburg.

Murdock, G.P. (1981). Atlas of World Cultures, University of Pittsburg Press, Pittsburg.

Murdock, G.P. and Spohr, A. (1967). "Ethnographic atlas XXXIII", Ethnology 6, 481-487.

Murdock, G.P. and Spohr, A. (1968a). "Ethnographic atlas XXXIV", Ethnology 7, 106-111.

Murdock, G.P. and Spohr, A. (1968b). "Ethnographic atlas XXXV", Ethnology 7, 218-224.

Murdock, G.P. and Spohr, A. (1968c). "Ethnographic atlas XXXVI", Ethnology 7, 327-329.

Rennell, F.J., alias Rodd, F.R. (1926). People of the Veil, Clowes, London.

Roth, W.E. (1908). "An inquiry into the animism and folk-lore of the Guiana Indians", Annual Reports of the Bureau of American Ethnology 30, 103-386.

Roth, W.E. (1916). "An introductory study of the arts, crafts, and customs of the Guiana Indians", Annual Reports of the Bureau of American Ethnology 38, 23-745.

Roth, W.E. (Ed. & Trans.) (1922-1923). Richard Schomburgk's Travels in British Guiana, Daily Chronicle, Georgetown.

Rudmin, F.W. (1988). "Dominance, social control, and ownership: A history and a cross-cultural study of motivations for private property", Behavior Science Research 22, 130-160. [Note: The first two galley pages were reversed during printing. The paper should begin on paragraph 5 on page 132. Paragraphs 1 through 4 should follow paragraph 8 on page 133.]

Rudmin, F.W. (1990). "The economic psychology of Leon Litwinski (1887-1969): A program of cognitive research on possession and property". Journal of Economic Psychology 11, 307-339.

Rudmin, F.W. (1992a). "Cross-cultural correlates of ownership of private property", Social Science Research 21, 57-83.

Rudmin, F.W. (1992b). "Cross-cultural correlates of ownership of private property: A look from another data base", Anthroplogica 34, 71-88.

Rudmin, F.W. (1993). "Ownership of economic property: McClelland's 1961 cross-cultural data", Psychological Reports 73, 794.

Rudmin, F.W. (1995). "Cross-cultural correlates of the ownership of private property: Two samples of Murdock's data", Journal of Socio-Economics 24, 345-373.

Rudmin, F.W. (1996). "Cross-cultural correlates of the ownership of private property: Zelman's gender data revisited", Cross-Cultural Research 30, 115-153.

Rudmin, F.W., Belk, R.W. and Furby, L. (1987). Social science Bibliography on Property, Ownership, and Possession: 1580 Citations from Psychology, Anthropology, Sociology and Related Disciplines, Vance, Monticello, IL.

Roy, S.c (1912). The Mundas, Kuntaline Press, Calcutta.

Roy, S.C. (1935). The Hill Bhuiyas of Orissa, Man in India Office, Ranchi.

Schama, S. (1987). The Embarrassment of Riches, Collins, London.

Schlatter, R. (1951). Private Property: The History of an Idea, Rutgers University Press, New Brunswick, NJ.

Simmons, L.W. (1937). "Statistical correlations in the science of society", in Studies in the Science of Society (G.P. Murdock, Ed.), pp. 493-517, Yale University Press, New Haven.

Simmons, L.W. (1945). The Role of the Aged in Primitive Society, Yale University Press, New Haven.

Sumner, W.G., Keller, A.G. and Davie, M.R. (1927). The Science of Society, Yale University Press, New Haven.

Swanson, G.E. (1966). The Birth of the Gods: The Origin of Primitive Beliefs, 2nd printing, University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor. (Originally published in 1960.)

Tawney, R.H. (1926). Religion and the Rise of Capitalism: A Historical Study, Harcourt Brace, New York.

Textor, R.B. (1967). A Cross-Cultural Summary, Human Relations Area Files Press, New Haven, Ct.

Ubach, E. and Rackow, E. (1923). Sitte und Recht in Nordafrika, Enke, Stuttgart.

Veblen, T. (1899). Theory of the Leisure Class, Macmillan, New York.

Weber, M. (1930). The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, G. Allen and Unwin, London.

Zelman, E.A. (1974). Women's Rights and Women's Rites: A Cross-Cultural Study of Womanpower and Reproductive Ritual, doctoral dissertation, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor.


 
 

All material on this site is (c) copyright to the respective authors but may be copied or printed FOR PERSONAL USE.